文档库 最新最全的文档下载
当前位置:文档库 › The Productivity Effects of Services Liberalization Evidence

The Productivity Effects of Services Liberalization Evidence

The Productivity Effects of Services Liberalization Evidence
The Productivity Effects of Services Liberalization Evidence

The Productivity Effects of Services Liberalization

Evidence from the Czech Republic

April 25, 2006

Jens Arnold*

Beata S. Javorcik**

Aaditya Mattoo***

Abstract

While there is considerable empirical evidence on the impact of liberalizing trade in goods, the effects of services liberalization have not been empirically established. This study examines the link between services sector reforms and the productivity of manufacturing industries relying on services inputs. The results, based on firm-level data from the Czech Republic for the period 1998—2003, show a positive relationship between services sector reform and the performance of domestic firms in downstream manufacturing sectors. When several aspects of services liberalization are considered, namely the presence of foreign providers, privatization and the level of competition, we find that allowing foreign entry into services industries may be the key channel through which services liberalization contributes to improved performance of downstream manufacturing sectors. As most barriers to foreign investment today are not in goods but in services sectors, our findings may strengthen the argument for reform in this area.

Keywords: services liberalization, productivity, foreign direct investment

JEL Codes: L8, F2, D24

_________________________

* World Bank and Bocconi University, 1818 H Street, NW; MSN MC3-303; Washington, DC, 20433. Email: jarnold1@https://www.wendangku.net/doc/7b1892607.html,. ** World Bank and CEPR, 1818 H Street, NW; MSN MC3-303; Washington, DC, 20433. Email: bjavorcik@https://www.wendangku.net/doc/7b1892607.html,. *** World Bank, 1818 H Street, NW; MSN MC3-303; Washington, DC, 20433. Email: amattoo@https://www.wendangku.net/doc/7b1892607.html,. This paper is part of the World Bank’s research program on trade in services, which is supported in part by the United Kingdom’s Department for International Development. We thank Clinton Shiells and seminar participants at the World Bank, the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development, the London School of Economics, the Third CEPR Conference on "Trade, Industrialisation and Development" in Chianti, Italy and the Joint Vienna Institute for helpful comments. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the view of the World Bank, its Executive Directors, or the countries they represent.

1 Introduction

As reflected in recent policy debates in the European Union and the World Trade Organization, liberalization of services sectors has been a highly controversial subject. This controversy is exacerbated by the fact that in contrast to the considerable empirical evidence assessing the impact of trade liberalization in goods,1 little is known about the effects of allowing foreign providers greater access in services industries. Yet given the fact that a wide range of manufacturing and services industries rely on services inputs, large gains could potentially be achieved through liberalization of services sectors.

To the best of our knowledge, this is the first study documenting empirically the link between reforms in services sectors and the productivity of manufacturing industries relying on services inputs. Our analysis focuses on the Czech Republic which during the 1990s introduced far reaching reforms of services industries, including opening the sector to foreign investors. The results, based on firm level information for the period 1998—2003, suggest a positive association between the extent of policy reform in services industries and the productivity of the manufacturing sectors using services inputs.

Liberalization of services industries is likely to induce entry of new domestic or foreign providers and hence increase the choice of providers for downstream users of services. New entry may be encouraged through an introduction of regulation abolishing monopolies, privatization of formerly state owned enterprises or opening services sectors to foreign entrants. A greater choice of services providers may in turn affect the performance of manufacturing sectors in three ways.

First, the quality and reliability of services may improve as a result of privatization or entry of internationally successful players. For instance, international phone communications or electricity provision may become more reliable due to investments in infrastructure by new domestic owners or foreign shareholders, or credit decisions may be made faster as competition among banks increases. This will in turn limit disruptions to production and decrease the operating costs in downstream manufacturing sectors.

Second, new services may become available with the introduction of international best practice. Examples include new financial instruments and cash flow management tools, multi-modal transport services, or digital value-added services in telecommunications. Availability of such services may allow manufacturers to introduce productivity enhancing changes to their operations, such as for instance, receiving production orders on line or setting up on-line bidding systems for suppliers.

Third, services liberalization may also lead to a wider availability of services that were formerly restricted to certain groups of users, such as internet coverage in rural areas or an improved availability of business consulting services to smaller firms. The improved access may in turn enhance competitiveness of smaller or remotely located enterprises.

The entry of foreign providers may play a particularly important role. Foreign providers may bring into the country know-how and knowledge about new products and international best practice. By setting a higher standard and introducing new products, they may also induce domestic suppliers to make similar improvements. Given the limited scope for using cross-border trade to substitute for domestically produced services inputs, we would expect the performance of downstream sectors to be tied more directly to the quality and availability of services supplied by providers operating domestically than is the case for physical intermediate inputs.

1 For instance, Pavcnik (2002) and Fernandes (2003) examine the implications of trade liberalization on the productivity of firms in protected sectors, while Amiti and Konings (2005) distinguish between the effects of lowering tariffs on final goods and intermediate inputs.

The potential positive effect of liberalization and foreign presence in services sectors is reflected in the results of a firm survey conducted by the World Bank in the Czech Republic in 2004. A majority of the 350 Czech enterprises interviewed believed that liberalization of services industries contributed to improvements in quality, range and availability of services inputs in their country.

A closer look at services industries in the Czech Republic reveals substantial differences between domestic and foreign-owned services providers. Foreign-owned providers exhibit higher labor productivity than their domestic counterparts and have a higher propensity to invest. The data also documents increases in productivity and investment taking place following foreign acquisitions of Czech services firms. Moreover, the data show that following a foreign acquisition, target firms experience an increase in their market share, indicating a revealed consumer preference for the services provided by foreign-owned companies.

To examine the link between services sector reforms and the performance of services users, this study relates the total factor productivity of manufacturing firms to the state of liberalization in services sectors weighted by the respective manufacturing sector’s reliance on inputs from that services sector. The analysis is based on firm level data from Amadeus, a commercial data base including financial statements and ownership information for approximately ten thousand Czech companies for the 1998-2003 period. The reliance of manufacturing sectors on services inputs is assessed based on the national input-output matrix.

Several proxies are used to capture the extent of liberalization in services sectors. The first measure is a set of policy reform indices published by the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD). Sector-specific time-varying indices are available for banking, telecommunications, electric power, railway transport, road transport, and water distribution. The indices reflect the overall state of policy reform in a given services industry. The other three measures used capture a particular aspect of liberalization: (i) the extent to which foreign investors have entered Czech services industries, proxied by the share of an industry’s output produced by foreign-owned companies; (ii) the progress of privatization in services industries, proxied by share of an industry’s output produced by private companies; (iii) the level of competition in services industries, measured by the market share of the four largest providers.

In addition to proxies for services liberalization, the empirical analysis includes a comprehensive set of controls for other channels through which increased openness may affect firm performance. In particular, we control for the availability of material inputs provided by foreign-owned companies operating in upstream manufacturing sectors and for tariffs on imported intermediate inputs. To capture the level of competition in the output markets, we control for foreign presence and tariff protection in the same sector. The model includes firm fixed effects which control for unobserved firm heterogeneity and capture time-invariant effects specific to the industry and the region in which a firm operates. In our second specification, we estimate a model in first differences, including additionally a full set of fixed effects for industries, regions and years. To take into account the possible simultaneity between productivity shocks and input selection, we estimate the total factor productivity using the methodology proposed by Olley and Pakes (2003). Our results demonstrate a positive correlation between liberalization in services sectors and the productivity of manufacturing firms relying on services inputs. When each measure is considered in isolation, a positive and statistically significant relationship is found for the overall progress in policy reform, the presence of foreign providers in services sectors and the extent of privatization in services industries. No statistically significant relationship is detected for the level of competition in services sectors. When multiple measures are entered jointly, the effect of privatization loses its statistical significance. In our most demanding specification in first differences, we find that the relationship between the presence of foreign providers in services

sectors and the performance of manufacturing firms relying on services inputs is the most robust. We also confirm a positive and statistically significant association between the overall index of policy reforms and downstream productivity. Our findings are consistent with services sector liberalization, as manifested by foreign direct investment (FDI) inflows into the sector, being associated with improved availability, range and quality of services, which in turn contribute to improved performance of manufacturing firms using services as inputs.

In addition to the results for services inputs, there is some indication that better access to material inputs through increased foreign presence in upstream manufacturing sectors or lower tariffs on intermediates is positively related to the performance of manufacturing firms. Competition from foreign presence in the same sector and from imports from developing countries (as proxied by the MFN tariff) tends to be negatively correlated with productivity. However, these results are not statistically significant in all specifications.

Most of the barriers to foreign investment today are not in goods but in services (UNCTAD, 2004), reflecting the unwillingness of governments, particularly in developing countries, to allow unrestricted foreign presence in what they believe are “strategic” sectors. For example, even countries in South East Asia, such as Malaysia and Thailand, which have reaped huge benefits from the liberalization of trade and investment in goods continue to maintain restrictions on foreign ownership in services ranging from transport to telecommunications. India, which is emerging as a highly competitive supplier of a range of skilled labor-intensive services, still restricts foreign ownership in banking, insurance, telecommunications and retail distribution. Foreign entry into banking in Brazil and a number of other Latin American countries is subject to a high level of regulatory discretion, including in Brazil’s case the need to obtain a Presidential decree. Our analysis suggests that these restrictions on foreign presence in producer services can seriously dampen the growth of productivity in manufacturing.

This paper is structured as follows. Section 2 reviews the relevant literature. Section 3 discusses the liberalization of services industries in the Czech Republic. Section 4 describes the data and the empirical strategy, while section 5 contains the empirical results. The last section presents the conclusion of the study.

2 Related Literature

As Hoekman (2006) notes, “research on services trade constitutes only a very small share of the total output of international economics” and “the share of rigorous empirical studies [on services] is particularly small, reflecting the scarcity of data on both policies and flows.” The small existing literature encompasses a theoretical contribution by Francois (1990) who argues that the growth of intermediation services is an important determinant of overall economic growth and development and three econometric studies based on aggregate data. Rajan and Zingales (1998) examine the impact of financial sector development on growth in downstream industries and find that more finance-dependent sectors grow faster in countries with well-developed financial markets. Hoekman and Eschenbach (2006) document a positive correlation between the extent of services liberalization and economic growth in transition countries during the 1990-2004 period. Mattoo, Rathindran and Subramanian (2006) present econometric evidence from a sample of 60 countries over the 1990-1999 period that openness in the financial and telecommunications sectors influences long-run growth performance.2

2 A related literature considers the importance of services reform for goods trade. Francois and Wooton (2005) examine the interaction between competition in transportation and retail services, and trade in goods. They find that services liberalization can increase trade in goods, as long as it makes the market structure more competitive. Fink, Mattoo and Neagu (2005) show that communication costs matter for export performance for certain goods, and Freund and Weinhold (2002) find a trade-enhancing effect of internet connectivity.

To the best of our knowledge, the relationship between services reform and downstream productivity has not been previously examined in the empirical literature. This lack of existing evidence is particularly surprising considering the well-developed empirical literature with respect to other channels through which openness may affect firm performance.

The first channel which has received a lot of attention is the effect of trade liberalization on indigenous producers in import competing sectors and indigenous producers relying on imported inputs. In both cases, trade liberalization has been found to have a positive effect. For instance, Pavcnik (2002), who considers the Chilean trade liberalization, documents that plants in import-competing sectors grew by 3 to 10 percent more than those in sectors that were not exposed to foreign competition. Her findings suggest that Chilean plants had to improve their performance in response to exposure to competition from abroad. Fernandes (2003) demonstrates similar improvements in Colombia, as do Krishna and Mitra in India (1998), Muendler (2004) in Brazil and Javorcik and Goh (2006) in Poland. Analyzing the effects of trade liberalization in upstream manufacturing sectors, Amiti and Konings (2005) find a strong positive relationship between trade liberalization in intermediate inputs and firm productivity in downstream manufacturing sectors. Muendler (2004), however, concludes that this channel plays only a minor role.

The second channel that has been extensively investigated is the impact of foreign direct investment on indigenous firms. A large number of studies have considered the effect of foreign entry on indigenous producers operating in the same sector, postulating that foreign entry may result in knowledge spillovers to local firms (which would have a positive effect on the performance of the latter) as well as in local producers losing part of their market share to foreign entrants (which would have a negative effect as local producers who would have to spread their fixed cost over a smaller scale of production). Empirical analyses based on firm-level panel data find that the overall effect of these two forces is either negative or statistically insignificant (e.g., Aitken and Harrison 1999 on Venezuela, Djankov and Hoekman 2000 on the Czech Republic, Konings 2001 on Bulgaria, Poland and Romania, and Javorcik 2004 on Lithuania). More recently researchers have also analyzed inter-industry effects of foreign entry. Kugler (2005) documents a positive effect of FDI inflows on Colombian producers in other sectors. He considers the pairwise effects between sectors without distinguishing between the effects on downstream versus upstream sectors. Javorcik (2004), who distinguishes between the two channels, finds a positive effect of FDI on local producers in upstream industries and no significant effect on local producers in downstream manufacturing sectors in Lithuania.

While our focus in this paper is on the relationship between services liberalization and the performance of domestic firms in downstream manufacturing sectors, we will also examine the impact of trade liberalization and foreign presence in both own and upstream manufacturing sectors. First, however, we turn to the developments in services sectors in the Czech Republic.

3 Services Liberalization in the Czech Republic

3.1 Services Reform

Having made substantial progress in liberalizing services sectors and opening its economy to foreign direct investment, the Czech Republic is a suitable choice for our study. Within a few years after the end of the communist regime in 1989, the government of the former Czechoslovakia privatized many state-owned enterprises, liberalized prices and wage-setting and opened the country to foreign trade and FDI (Hanousek et al. 2004). In 1998, Czech policy makers adopted an even more welcoming approach to foreign direct investment, particularly in services industries, and FDI inflows saw a steep rise. FDI inflows in 1998 were twice as large as in the preceding year and doubled again in 1999. In total, more that than 40 billion euro of FDI

entered the country since 1993, making the Czech Republic the most successful Central and Eastern European country in terms of the stock of foreign direct investment per capita. Many of the world’s most prominent multinational companies have established themselves in the Czech market.

Figure 1 demonstrates that a majority of FDI inflows in the Czech Republic have been directed into services rather than manufacturing sectors. Policy makers in the Czech Republic have recognized from early on the importance of service sector reform and have implemented many measures to enhance competition in services. To name an example, the National Telecommunications Policy of the Czech Republic states that “The basic condition for a stable social and economic growth in the Czech Republic is a dynamic development of Telecommunications” (Skudder 2003). In this sector, massive privatization, opening the sector to foreign investors and the entry of new providers have caused major changes, with a choice of operators now existing in all segments of the market. According to WTO (2001), there has been “strong growth in both size and quality of services, and prices of some services have fallen.”

Other services industries have also become a prime target for FDI inflows. In the banking sector, the number of foreign banks and branches has been continuously rising since the first Czech Bank was privatized into foreign hands in 1992. Belgian, Austrian, German and US banks now hold significant stakes in the Czech financial sector, and the authorities estimate that foreign-controlled banks account for 70% of total assets in the sector (WTO 2001). Figure 2 depicts the distribution of FDI inflows across services industries during the period considered our study, 1998—2003.

The progress of the liberalization of the Czech economy with respect to both domestic regulation and openness to foreign entry was closely monitored by the European Union, in preparation for the country’s accession in 2004.3 The fact that substantial liberalization of services was required to attain one of the major policy goals of the Czech Republic lends considerable exogeneity to the pace of reform and suggests that services liberalization and openness to foreign entry were exogenous developments rather than a response to domestic lobbying. Appendix C contains a detailed description of the reform measures undertaken in the banking, telecommunications and energy sectors.

3.2 Anecdotal Evidence on the Effects of Services Reform

There is considerable anecdotal evidence suggesting that quality improvements and the introduction of new services in the Czech Republic have been related to the liberalization of services industries and the presence of foreign providers. For example, the Czech Republic was lagging behind all its Western European neighbors with respect to the use of cellular phones in 1998, which is the first year considered in our analysis. By 2003, however, it was second only to Italy and Sweden with respect to the number of cell phones per 100 inhabitants (see Figure 3). Similarly, with respect to the number of internet users per 100 inhabitants, the country has advanced from being at the bottom of the ranking in 1998 to a middle position in 2003, leaving behind countries such as Greece, Spain and Portugal. In 2003, the Czech Republic had almost the same proportion of internet users in its population as Ireland and Italy. It is also suggestive that in countries such as Bulgaria, Russia, Romania and Ukraine, where little progress was made with respect to services liberalization and little foreign investment has taken place, internet usage remains at the level of 0.05 to 0.15 internet users per 100 people, which is an order of magnitude lower than the corresponding figure for the Czech Republic.

3 The European Commission published extensive yearly reports on “Progress towards Accession” on its website at http://europa.eu.int/comm/enlargement.

Banking is another example of a sector where foreign firms have been at the forefront of introducing innovative services in the Czech market. Ceska Sporitelna, a large Austrian-owned bank, installed 1,080 ATMs across the country and issued 2.7 million payment cards by early 2005. It was also the first bank to offer transaction ATMs, at which customers could pay their bills or make transfers. Moreover, it has become the market leader in remote banking, offering services via phone, cell phone or internet. When Ceska Sporitelna introduced a new internet banking service in 2002, 70,000 Czech customers signed up for the new service during the first 2 months. By now, the service has about 800,000 users.

Foreign banks were also the first to speed up processing of loan applications. For instance, at the US-owned GE Capital Bank decisions about loans to small and medium enterprises are made within 2 days. Ceska Sporitelna guarantees the issuance of any debit card within 6 days from the filing of the application. HVB Bank, another foreign-owned bank, offers its corporate clients a software package that allows internet banking with multiple banks, domestic and international transactions, and multiple approval procedures of transactions within the company via electronic signatures, even if one of the approvers is located abroad. These changes suggest that liberalization and opening services sectors to foreign entry have brought considerable changes to the nature of the services sectors in the Czech Republic.

3.3 Survey Evidence on the Effects of Services Reform

Consistent with the anecdotal evidence, Czech managers exhibit very positive views of services sector reforms in their country. In 2004, the World Bank surveyed 350 Czech firms about their perceptions regarding different aspects of the services reform. Managers were asked whether they felt that the changes had a positive or a negative impact on their firms with regard to quality, prices, the range of services on offer and the availability of these services. As illustrated in Figure 4, the results of the survey portrayed a generally positive view of services reform. The share of positive perceptions ranged from 55% of the respondents when asked about the quality of accounting and auditing services to 82% for telecommunications. With regards to the variety of products offered, the positive views of liberalization varied between 56% of respondents evaluating accounting and auditing services to 87% of respondents asked about telecommunications. The corresponding figures for the effect on services availability ranged from 47% in accounting and auditing to 80% in telecommunications.4

3.4 Documenting Superior Performance of Foreign Services Providers

To shed more light on developments in services industries we take a closer look at services providers and explore the extent to which there exist systematic differences between domestic and foreign-owned firms with respect to a number of performance indicators between 1998 and 2003. We do so by estimating a simple model

it reg t j i it it D D D size foreign Y εμθκγβα+?+?+?+?+?+= (1)

where foreign it is a dummy variable taking on the value of one if the foreign ownership share in firm i at time t exceeded 10% and zero otherwise, size i captures the initial size of each company as measured by the logarithm of employment in the initial year of the sample 1998, and D j , D t and D reg are fixed effects for industries, years and regions. The model is estimated on a sample of services industries.

The source of firm-level information is the Amadeus data base published by Bureau van Dijk. It contains annual balance sheets and income statements of firms operating in the Czech Republic.

4 For exact wording of the survey questions, see Appendix A.

The data base includes all firms that either had total assets of more than 20 million Czech Crowns (CZK) or a turnover of more than 40 million CZK. The firm records contain information on volume of sales, labor and intermediate inputs, stock of tangible fixed assets, and ownership structure. To obtain the largest possible sample, we use information from several releases of the Amadeus data base and focus on the period 1998—2003.5 Nominal values of output are deflated using wholesale deflators specific to 3-digit NACE sectors, obtained from the Czech Statistical Office (CSO). For capital, a deflator for tangible fixed assets, obtained from the CSO, is used. TABLE 1. Performance premiums of foreign services firms and foreign acquisition targets

Foreign Premium Post-Acq.

Premium

Post-Acq.

Premium

Difference Test

Pre/Post Acq.

Labor Productivity Foreign Premium 0.758*** 1.011*** 1.078***

(Log Val Add p.w.) Pre-Acq. Period 0.621*** F

= 4.91** Log Investment Premium 1.004*** 0.843*** 0.880***

(Capital Growth) Pre-Acq. Period 0.594*** F

= 2.74* Market Share Premium 0.013*** 0.016*** 0.017***

Pre-Acq.

Period 0.009*** F

=14.34*** Initial Size Yes Yes Yes Industry FE Yes Yes Yes

Region FE Yes Yes Yes

Year FE Yes Yes Yes

Sample All services

firms

Excluding

always

foreign firms

Excluding

always

foreign firms

The premiums are estimated coefficients on a binary variable for foreign ownership or post-acquisition years in the case of firms

that were acquired by foreigners. The pre-acquisition period of future acquisition targets is also captured by a dummy variable,

and the last column tests for equality of the coefficients on the pre- and post-acquisition dummies. Initial size is controlled by the

log of employees in 1998. All regressions control for industry, region and year fixed effects. The number of observations in these regressions ranges from 5096 for labor productivity (due to missing values in employment) and 8092 for market share.

The results, presented in table 1, suggest that there exist significant differences between domestic and foreign-owned firms operating in services industries. Foreign-owned services firms have a significantly higher labor productivity, investment outlays and market shares. Although these results document systematic differences related to ownership, they cannot be interpreted as causal evidence. While a careful analysis of the direction of causality is beyond the scope of this paper, we can go a step further and exploit the within-firm ownership changes due to 280 foreign acquisitions that we observe in services industries in our data set.6 If the performance differences are related to ownership differences per se, we would expect to observe changes in these variables in firms changing their ownership status from domestic to foreign. Thus, in the second column of table 1, we exclude firms under foreign ownership throughout the period and let the foreign ownership indicator capture post-acquisition periods of the acquired firms. As before, we find that firms under foreign ownership exhibit positive and statistically significant performance premiums. In the models presented in the third column of table 1, we include two indicator variables: a dummy for the acquired firms observed one year before the ownership change and a dummy for the acquired firms observed after the ownership change. The coefficients on both variables are positive and statistically significant which suggests that firms changing ownership exhibit superior performance before as well as after being acquired, with the latter premium being larger. The 5 As happens with most large firm-level data sets, Amadeus contains cases of obvious key punch errors. In many of these cases, we are able to obtain the correct information from account statements on the company websites. In the remaining cases, we apply rules to identify and remove probable data errors from our sample, as outlined in Appendix B.

6 For a more complete econometric analysis of the causal relationship between foreign ownership and firm performance in manufacturing sectors in Indonesia, see Arnold and Javorcik (2005).

difference between the two coefficients is statistically significant and thus presents further evidence in favor of positive performance effects associated with foreign ownership. The fact that firms increase their market share after being acquired by foreign capital is also an indication that services users value performance differences associated with foreign ownership.

In summary, the anecdotal and the survey evidence as well as the econometric results documenting superior performance of foreign services providers suggest that service sector reform, and particularly foreign presence in these sectors, have left a positive mark on these industries. In the next section, we explore the implications of these changes for the manufacturing industries that rely on services inputs, which is the main objective of our analysis.

4 Empirical Strategy

Our firm-level data include information on firms in 21 manufacturing industries.7 We estimate total factor productivity (TFP) for all manufacturing firms as our measure of firm performance. TFP is estimated as the residual of a three-factor Cobb-Douglas production function, with deflated values of labor, capital and materials as production factors.8 We estimate the production function separately for 2-digit manufacturing sectors, using both ordinary least squares (OLS) and the semi-parametric estimation technique suggested by Olley and Pakes (1996). The latter technique controls for a possible simultaneity bias arising from the endogeneity of a firm’s input selection, which will exist if a firm responds to productivity shocks unobservable to the econometrician by adjusting its input choices. Such a behavior would establish a correlation between an explanatory variable and the error term in the estimation of the production function, thus violating one of the basic requirements for the validity of the OLS estimation. The Olley and Pakes estimator corrects for the possible bias that may result from this correlation by using the firm’s investment decision as a proxy for unobserved productivity shocks.9 The estimated TFP is then related to the extent of liberalization in services industries.

Liberalization of services industries is measured in several ways. The first measure comes from the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development publication Transition Report 2004. The EBRD publishes indices of policy reform for banking, telecommunications, electric power, railway transport, road transport, and water distribution as well as an overall index for services sectors. We use the overall index for those services industries where sector-specific information is not available. All of the indices are available for 1998—2002. According to the EBRD, the scores “reflect the judgment of the EBRD’s Office of the Chief Economist about country-specific progress in transition.” The advantage of using these measures is that they are in principle designed to encompass all policy aspects of liberalization, both with respect to domestic and foreign providers.10However, this broad coverage comes at the cost of a limited precision, particularly with respect to the time variation of the indicators.

Therefore, we employ alternative measures aiming to capture particular aspects of services reform, namely (i) the extent to which foreign investors have entered Czech services industries;

7 The petroleum sector (NACE 23) was excluded from the analysis because of a very small number of observations.

8 Nominal values of output and material inputs are deflated using wholesale deflators specific to 3-digit NACE sectors, obtained from the Czech Statistical Office (CSO). Labor costs are deflated using the consumer price index. For capital, a deflator for tangible fixed assets, obtained from the CSO, is used. As happens with most large firm-level data sets, Amadeus contains cases of obvious key punch errors. In many of these cases, we are able to obtain the correct information from account statements on the company websites. In the remaining cases, we apply rules to identify and remove probable data errors from our sample, as outlined in Appendix B.

9 Details of the procedure are outlined in Olley and Pakes (1996), as well as in other papers that applied the procedure in the context of international trade and investment, such as Pavcnik (2002), Javorcik (2004) and Arnold and Hussinger (2005).

10 The indices are described in more detail in Appendix D.

(ii) the progress of privatization in services industries; and (iii) the level of competition in services industries. These proxies offer several advantages. For one, they can be measured precisely. Second, allowing foreign entry or privatizing state owned enterprises is a good indicator of a serious commitment to reform. Third, all these measures are outcomes rather than policy variables, which means that they encompass implementation as well as policies. Fourth, comparing the results for individual measure can offer insights into the relative importance of various aspects of services liberalization.

The extent of foreign presence in services sectors is proxied by the share of foreign-owned providers in sectoral sales. Firm-level ownership information is available in Amadeus in the form of records on shareholders, their nationalities and their ownership shares, including the dates as of which the information is valid. The date records pertain to the latest available information in each release of Amadeus, i.e. they are not time-varying within one version of the data base. Therefore, we combine the information from four different releases of Amadeus (1998, October 2001, January 2005 and March 2005) and construct a panel of foreign ownership shares for each firm. In cases where the date of foreign entry was ambiguous, we looked up information on the owners from other publicly available sources. This usually allowed us to eliminate any residual doubts. For the top 5 companies in each sector and year, we additionally verified any available information about foreign owners and their date of entry of by looking at annual reports and information on the company websites.

Throughout the paper, we employ two definitions of foreign ownership shares: a threshold definition and a capital share definition. In the former, a firm’s entire output is counted as foreign if the sum of the shares held by foreign entities exceeds 10%, while in the latter a firm’s output is weighted by the foreign ownership share and only this fraction is considered as foreign output. Using these two definitions, we calculate the share of foreign output at the level of 2-digit services sectors of the NACE classification for the years 1998 to 2002. In what follows, we will refer to the foreign output share variables as foreign share.

We construct the foreign share variables for the following services sectors: other business activities (includes legal, accounting, consulting, advertising services) (NACE code 74), computer and related activities (72), renting of machinery and equipment (71), real estate activities (70), financial intermediation (65), post and telecommunications (64), supporting and auxiliary transport activities (63), land transport (60), retail trade and repair of personal and household goods (52), wholesale trade and commission trade (51), sale, maintenance and repair of motor vehicles and retail sale of automotive fuel (50), construction (45), collection, purification and distribution of water (41), electricity, gas and hot water supply (40).11 Foreign engagement in these sectors varies substantially. While in the electricity sector almost 76% of sales in 2002 came from firms with at least 10% foreign ownership, this ratio reached only 8% in land transport. There is also a significant variation across time. The average of foreign output shares more than doubled between 1998 and 2002.

The progress of privatization in services industries is proxied by the share of output provided by firms with private owners. The determination on whether a particular owner is a private entity or a state or municipal government or agency is made based on the shareholder name and description in the Amadeus data base. Then the output of each services provider is weighted by the share of equity under private ownership. All shares in a given industry and year are summed to create the measure of the progress in privatization.

11 The following services sector had to be excluded due to a small number of observations in the data: hotels and restaurants (55), water transport (61), air transport (62), insurance and pension funding (66), activities auxiliary to financial intermediation (67).

The level of competition in each services industry is proxied by two indices of concentration: the market share of the four largest providers and the Herfindahl index which is defined as the sum of squared market shares of all providers in the sector. As there is no qualitative difference between the findings based on the two indices, we present the estimation results only for the former index.

Since we are interested in inter-sectoral linkages between services and manufacturing industries, we need to weigh the extent of liberalization in each services sector by the reliance of manufacturing firms on each services input. While we do not have information on services inputs at the level of individual firms, we can use information from a national input-output matrix to evaluate inter-industry dependencies between individual manufacturing and services sectors.12 An advantage of using the industry level information is that there is less need to be concerned about a correlation between the performance of an individual firm and its services usage. Based on the information on the relative importance of each services sector for manufacturing industries, we calculate the following measures for each manufacturing industry j at time t :

kt

k jk jt index tion liberaliza a linkage services __?=∑

(2) where a jk is the amount of inputs sourced from services sector k , expressed as a fraction of the overall inputs used by manufacturing sector j. Liberalization_index kt is one of the five measures discussed above: the EBRD index of reform in services sector k at time t , foreign share kt defined based on capital shares or thresholds for services sector k at time t , the share of output provided by private companies in services sector k at time t or the concentration index for services sector k at time t . Put differently, the services_linkage variable is obtained by multiplying the matrix of sectoral reform indicators for services sectors with a matrix of input-output coefficients.13

To establish whether there exists a link between the performance of Czech firms and liberalization of upstream services sectors, we regress the productivity of manufacturing firms on the services_linkage measures:

it i jt jt it D X linkage services TFP ηδγβα+?+?+?+=??11_

(3)

where TFP it is the total factor productivity of a Czech manufacturing firm i operating at time t estimated at the industry level using alternatively ordinary least squares or the semiparametric Olley and Pakes method, X jt-1 is a vector of controls for other aspects of the increasing integration of the Czech economy with the outside world and D i is the vector of firm fixed effects capturing unobserved firm heterogeneity. Since we are interested in the effect on domestic manufacturing firms, only firms in manufacturing sectors (NACE Codes 15 to 36) that have less than 10% of foreign ownership at all times are considered in the regressions. As the effects of services liberalization and other aspects of international integration may take time to materialize, the variables enter the model as one period lags.

The vector X jt-1 includes a sector-specific measure of foreign presence in upstream manufacturing sectors, constructed in the same way as the services_linkage variables. Foreign entry into manufacturing industries may affect the sourcing options for manufacturing inputs by increasing the quality and range of products available. To account for the sourcing options offered by imported inputs, X jt-1 also includes the level of tariff protection in upstream manufacturing sectors, again weighted by the input-output coefficients. Our tariff measures are applied MFN tariffs. In preparation for accession to the European Union, Czech tariffs vis-à-vis the EU were governed by a bilateral accession agreement of 1992, which established a schedule for phasing out

12

We employ the use table of the input-output matrix for the year 2000, obtained from the CSO. Ideally, we would want to have annual information, but unfortunately it is not available. Note, however, that the year 2000 lies approximately in the middle of the time period covered by our sample.

13 This way of measuring cross-sector effects was used by, for instance, Javorcik (2004).

tariffs on most manufacturing products by the end of 2000. In practice, this means that for the time frame we are investigating, EU preferential tariffs outside the food and tobacco sectors were already at a very low level, with an average tariff of less than half a percent. In the presence of virtual free trade with the EU then, it does not seem sensible to exploit the minimal variation in this protection before 2001, and indeed our data show no evidence that this aspect of trade protection matters. Instead we focus on MFN tariffs, which will mainly capture protection vis-à-vis imports those from developing countries, such as China. In Appendix E, however, we repeat some of our basic regressions including both EU preferential and MFN tariff rates.

Finally, to control for the level of competition and possible knowledge spillovers, we also include measures of foreign entry into a firm’s own sector as well as the level of tariff protection in the same sector.14 To take into account other factors that may generate a correlation between the performance of manufacturing firms and foreign entry into services sectors, such as for instance, regional differences in remoteness or quality of infrastructure, or events that improve business prospects in both services and manufacturing in a specific year, we include firm and year fixed effects. The firm fixed effects will also control for unobserved heterogeneity of firms. 15

In our second specification, we estimate the model in first differences rather than in levels. Differencing takes out all observable and unobservable time-invariant characteristics at the level of the firm as well as at the level of the industry and region. By further including the full set of industry, region and year fixed effects in the model in first differences, we additionally control for differences in trends (rather than in levels) that are specific to the industry or region in question or for factors affecting the whole economy in a particular period. For example, differences in regional dynamics, or expansionary or contractionary trends of certain industries would be picked up by these fixed effects in the differenced equation and would not bias our coefficient estimate of the services linkage variable. Our second specification takes the following form:

it reg t j jt jt it D D D X linkage services TFP ωμθκ?φν+?+?+?+?Δ+Δ?+=Δ??11_

(4)

5 Results

The results from the estimation of equation 3 using OLS productivity estimates are shown in table 2. When we enter the measures of services_linkages into the model one by one, we find a positive and statistically significant correlation between the firm performance in downstream manufacturing and the overall liberalization of services (EBRD measure, equations I and II), the presence of foreign providers of services (measured using the two alternative definitions of foreign output in equations III and IV) and the extent of privatization in services industries (equation V). For the EBRD and FDI measures the effect is significant at the one percent level. These results support our hypothesis that services liberalization affects the performance of domestic manufacturing firms relying on services inputs. The extent of competition in services, proxied by the concentration ratio (or the Herfindahl index, not reported to save space), does not appear to have a statistically significant effect. When the three aspects of services reform (foreign presence, privatization and competition) enter the model jointly in equations VII and VIII, only the presence of foreign providers is statistically significant. This suggests that allowing foreign entry into services industries may be the key channel through which services liberalization contributes to improved performance of downstream manufacturing sectors.

14

We have also experimented with concentration measures in the same sector, but these turned out to have no systematic significant effect.

15 All of the regressions presented in section 5 include domestic manufacturing firms only. We have repeated the exercise including both domestic and foreign firms, and obtained very similar results.

Moreover, our results suggest that access to foreign-produced material inputs and the level of competition in product markets may also affect the performance of manufacturing firms. Access to material inputs produced by foreign investors exhibits a significant and positive correlation with the downstream performance in half of the specifications. Tariff protection in manufacturing industries supplying inputs displays a significant negative relationship with downstream performance in 4 out of 8 cases. This result is consistent with the findings by Amiti and Konings (2005) showing that trade liberalization benefits users of imported inputs. Foreign presence in the same sector tends to be negatively correlated with the productivity of Czech firms, albeit this effect is statistically significant only in some specifications. The negative coefficient estimate is in line with the results of Djankov and Hoekman (2000) obtained for the Czech Republic for an earlier period. Tariff protection in the own sector displays a positive relationship with firm performance. While this finding contrasts with the results on the effect of import competition on productivity in the existing literature, it is important to mention that our result is not directly comparable to those found in other analyses. Our tariff measure captures mainly competition from developing country imports as throughout most of the period under study, imports of manufacturing products from the European Union and its accession countries were entering the Czech Republic practically duty free.16

In order to interpret the size of our estimated coefficients, we undertake the following hypothetical exercises on the basis of models I and III of table 2. Assume that the level of services liberalization of the Czech Republic at the end of our time frame, as measured by the EBRD Transition Indices, were to drop to the level of Romania, which has made considerably less progress in liberalizing its services sectors according to the EBRD. In this case, our model would predict an average decrease in productivity in downstream manufacturing sectors of the order of 4.6%. With respect to foreign presence, simulating that foreign output shares in all services sectors considered were to increase uniformly by 10 percentage points, our model predicts a downstream productivity increase of the order of 3%. For upstream manufacturing sectors, we would expect a uniform increase in foreign presence of 10 percentage points to be associated with

a 6% increase in downstream manufacturing.

16 In Appendix E, we have estimated the same models as in table 2 using EU-preferential tariffs in addition to the MFN tariffs. While the preferential tariff measures are insignificant in these regressions, the results for services reform remain largely unchanged.

TABLE 2. Estimation with firm fixed effects using OLS Productivities:

Productivity in Domestic Manufacturing Firms and Reform in Upstream Services Sectors Dependent Variable: TFP

I II III IV V VI VII VIII EBRD 1.066** 1.239*** [0.421] [0.421] FDI 3.225*** 3.578** Services

Inputs

Linkage

(Threshold) [0.941] [1.577] FDI 8.233*** 7.95***

(Cap Share) [1.921] [2.549]

Privatization 10.559* -2.435 2.245

[5.925] [5.399] [4.535]

Concentration -1.666 -0.231 1.288

[3.095] [3.900] [3.328]

FDI 0.957*** 0.969*** 1.010** (Threshold) [0.344] [0.334] [0.441] FDI 0.546 1.129* 0.458 0.332 1.056 Manufacturing

Inputs

Linkage

(Cap Share) [0.593] [0.611] [0.602] [0.725] [0.676] Tariffs -0.144*** -0.150* -0.268*** -0.341***-0.090 -0.035 -0.279 -0.344

[0.051] [0.076] [0.071] [0.093] [0.082] [0.080] [0.087] [0.097]

FDI -0.179 -0.253** -0.289*** -0.501*** Competition

within sector

(Threshold) [0.144] [0.106] [0.178] [0.264] FDI -0.252 -0.542** -0.155 -0.133

(Cap Share) [0.244] [0.224] [0.275] [0.331] Tariffs 0.069*** 0.072* 0.123*** 0.154*** 0.032 0.016 0.130** 0.156**

[0.025] [0.037] [0.032] [0.042] [0.040] [0.039] [0.042] [0.048]

Dummies Firm FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

R 2 0.18 0.177 0.178 0.174 0.176 0.174 0.182 0.182

N

4679 4679 4679 4679 4679 4679 4679 4679 The Inputs Linkage variables are weighted by the respective I/O coefficient. All regressors are lagged one year. Robust standard errors are presented in brackets. *, **, *** indicate statistical significance at the 10, 5 and 1% level.

In table 3, we present the same estimates based on TFP measures obtained using Olley and Pakes (O/P). These results lead to the same conclusions: We find a positive and significant relationship between the reform in services sectors, as reflected by the EBRD index, foreign presence and privatization, and the performance of Czech firms in downstream manufacturing. Again, the presence of foreign services providers appears to have the most robust effect on the performance of Czech firms in downstream manufacturing.

TABLE 3. Estimation with firm fixed effects using Olley/Pakes Productivities:

Productivity in Domestic Manufacturing Firms and Reform in Upstream Services Sectors

Dependent Variable: TFP

I II III IV V VI VII VIII EBRD 0.985** 1.194*** Services

Inputs

Linkage

[0.405] [0.413] FDI 2.942*** 2.952

(Threshold) [1.010] [1.759] FDI 8.086*** 7.344**

(Cap Share) [2.028] [2.879]

Privatization 12.037** -.0104 4.060

[5.002] [6.080] [4.995]

Concentration -2.566 -.0337 0.571

[2.962] [3.698] [3.321]

FDI 0.930** 0.938** 0.955 Manufacturing

Inputs

Linkage

(Threshold) [0.408] [0.405] [0.490] FDI 0.464 1.043 0.423 0.328 1.014

(Cap Share) [0.702] [0.703] [0.672] [0.808] [0.741] Tariffs -0.135* -0.150 -0.247***-0.339***-0.101 -0.037 -0.247** -0.333***

[0.074] [0.095] [0.088] [0.110] [0.091] [0.088] [0.105] [0.115]

FDI -0.126 -0.192 -0.201 -0.444 Competition

within sector

(Threshold) [0.156] [0.120] [0.190] [0.285] FDI -0.187 -0.475* -0.106 -0.103

(Cap Share) 0.273 [0.249] [0.294] [0.352] Tariffs 0.065* 0.072 0.114*** 0.15***4 0.035 0.015 0.114** 0.148***

[0.035] [0.046] [0.040] [0.049] [0.044] [0.042] [0.050] [0.055]

Dummies

Firm FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes R 2 0.172 0.168 0.174 0.173 0.176 0.165 0.174 0.173

N

4679 4679 4679 4679 4679 4679 4679 4679 The Inputs Linkage variables are weighted by the respective I/O coefficient. All regressors are lagged one year. Robust standard errors are presented in brackets. *, **, *** indicate statistical significance at the 10, 5 and 1% level.

To further demonstrate the robustness of our results, we present additional specifications containing proxies for services reforms entering in various combinations. Tables 4 and 5 present these results for the OLS and O/P specifications, respectively. When multiple measures are considered in the same specification only the overall progress in services reform (EBRD index) and the presence of foreign providers are statistically significant, with the latter variable being more robust. This lends support to our earlier finding that allowing foreign entry is a key channel through which services liberalization may benefit local producers relying on services inputs.

TABLE 4. Estimation with firm fixed effects using OLS Productivities:

Productivity in Domestic Manufacturing Firms and Reform in Upstream Services Sectors Dependent Variable: TFP

I II III IV V VI EBRD 0.708*** 0.195 0.724*** 0.107 0.736*** 0.253 Services

Inputs

Linkage

[0.243] [0.298] [0.269] [0.251] [0.230] [0.284] FDI 2.803* 2.768*** 2.692*

(Threshold) [1.445] [0.816] [1.491] FDI 7.235** 8.089*** 7.132**

(Cap Share) [3.191] [1.972] [3.122]

Privatization -0.244 2.374 0.478 3.235

[5.458] [5.659] [5.245] [4.992]

Concentration 0.736 0.996 0.851 1.532

[3.517] [3.384] [3.600] [3.264]

FDI 1.081*** 1.045** 1.035** Manufacturing Inputs Linkage

(Threshold) [0.329] [0.430] [0.435] FDI 1.128* 1.069 1.038

(Cap Share) [0.592] [0.705] [0.678]

Tariffs -0.311*** -0.334***-0.310***-0.347*** -0.308*** -0.342***

[0.095] [0.101] [0.085] [0.095] [0.095] [0.101]

FDI -0.313*** -0.294 -0.289 Competition

within sector

(Threshold) [0.101] [0.174] [0.178] FDI -0.532** -0.517* -0.490*

(Cap Share) [0.220] [0.273] [0.269] Tariffs 0.144*** 0.149*** 0.144*** 0.159*** 0.143*** 0.155***

[0.046] [0.049] [0.039] [0.044] [0.045] [0.050]

Dummies Firm FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes R 2 0.183 0.182 0.183 0.182 0.183 0.182

N

4679 4679 4679 4679 4679 4679 The Inputs Linkage variables are weighted by the respective I/O coefficient. All regressors are lagged one year.

Robust standard errors are presented in brackets. *, **, *** indicate statistical significance at the 10, 5 and 1%

level.

TABLE 5. Estimation with firm fixed effects using Olley/Pakes Productivities:

Productivity in Domestic Manufacturing Firms and Reform in Upstream Services Sectors

Dependent Variable: TFP

I II III IV V VI EBRD 0.711*** 0.258 0.665** 0.056 0.736*** 0.290 Services

Inputs

Linkage

[0.228] [0.328] [0.264] [0.236] [0.220] [0.310] FDI 2.164 2.514*** 2.066

(Threshold) [1.658] [0.904] [1.722] FDI 6.472* 7.941*** 6.405*

(Cap Share) [3.640] [2.128] [3.593]

Privatization 2.177 4.719 2.809 5.197

[5.826] [6.071] [6.066] [5.715]

Concentration 0.069 -0.010 0.745 0.851

[3.241] [3.287] [3.428] [3.245]

FDI 1.020** 1.037** 0.980* Manufacturing Inputs Linkage

(Threshold) [0.402] [0.487] [0.488] FDI 1.043 1.042 0.994

(Cap Share) [0.660] [0.783] [0.740]

Tariffs -0.279*** -0.327*** -0.286*** -0.339*** -0.277** -0.331***

[0.112] [0.119] [0.104] [0.111] [0.113] [0.119]

FDI -0.236** -0.245 -0.215 Competition

within sector

(Threshold) [0.112] [0.179] [0.181] FDI -0.454* -0.475 -0.431

(Cap Share) [0.241] [0.294] [0.287] Tariffs 0.128** 0.143** 0.133*** 0.154*** 0.127** 0.146**

[0.054] [0.056] [0.047] [0.050] [0.054] [0.057]

Dummies Firm FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes R 2 0.175 0.173 0.183 0.182 0.175 0.173

N

4679 4679 4679 4679 4679 4679 The Inputs Linkage variables are weighted by the respective I/O coefficient. All regressors are lagged one year.

Robust standard errors are presented in brackets. *, **, *** indicate statistical significance at the 10, 5 and 1%

level.

The above findings indicate a correlation between services liberalization and performance. In order to present some evidence that reverse causality is an unlikely problem in our estimation, we extend the lags of the independent variables in our equation to two years. The results from these specification are presented in table 6 for OLS TFP measures (columns 1 and 2) and Olley and Pakes-corrected TFP estimates (columns 3 and 4). They demonstrate that our basic conclusion regarding the importance of foreign entry into services sectors holds when we expand number of the lags with which the independent variables enter the regressions. Since it is unlikely that the productivity of manufacturing firms today is relevant for FDI inflows into services sectors two years ago, we feel reasonably confident that reverse causation is unlikely to be a problem in this specification. One should also keep in mind that the customer base of foreign entrants into services sectors goes well beyond manufacturing firms; future sales to households and firms in services sectors are likely to be taken into consideration when FDI decisions are made. Table 6 presents the results based on the threshold definition of foreign presence which is statistically

significant in all specifications. Using the capital share definition would lead to the same conclusions.

TABLE 6. Estimation with 2-year lags using OLS (I-II) and Olley/Pakes (III-IV) TFP

Productivity in Domestic Manufacturing Firms and Reform in Upstream Services Sectors

Dependent Variable: TFP

I II III IV EBRD 0.631 0.246 Services Inputs

Linkage

[1.135] [1.136] FDI 3.138*** 3.011*** 2.857*** 2.807***

(Threshold) [0.670] [0.726] [0.885] [0.951]

Concentration 1.685 0.645

[3.780] [4.343]

FDI 1.091** 1.046* 1.100 1.083 Manufacturing

Inputs Linkage

(Threshold) [0.529] [0.556] [0.655] [0.652] Tariffs -0.345*** -0.351*** -0.373*** -0.375***

[0.069] [0.069] [0.081] [0.085]

FDI -0.307*** -0.281* -0.259** -0.250 Competition

within sector

(Threshold) [0.100] [0.148] [0.114] [0.162] Tariffs 0.152*** 0.158*** 0.168*** -0.170***

[0.033] [0.033] [0.040] [0.040]

Dummies

Firm FE Yes Yes Yes Yes

Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes R 2 0.146

0.147 0.143 0.143 N 2593 2593 2593 2593

The Inputs Linkage variables are weighted by the respective I/O coefficient. All regressors are lagged

two years. Robust standard errors are presented in brackets. *, **, *** indicate statistical significance

at the 10, 5 and 1% level.

As the next step, we estimate our model in first differences as specified in equation 4, rather than using our previous firm fixed effects specification in levels. In this more demanding specification, the differencing removes all influences that are fixed at the level of the firm, industry or region, as did the firm fixed effects before. In addition, dummy variables in the differenced equation now purge all differences in trends that are specific to an industry or region. Moreover, in this specification, we adjust standard errors to allow for a correlation between observations belonging to the same industry.

These estimates, presented in table 7, confirm our earlier conclusions. In all specifications, we find a positive and statistically significant correlation between the presence of foreign providers of services and the productivity of Czech firms relying on services inputs. We present the results based on the threshold definition, however, using the capital share definition would lead to the same conclusions. We also find a similar relationship for our measure of the overall progress in services liberalization (EBRD measure). In this case, however, a statistically significant relationship is obtained in 4 out of 6 regressions. With respect to the other variables in our regression, the results are less clear-cut in this more demanding specification. None of the variables except the two mentioned above is significant in more than one specification.

TABLE 7. Estimation in first differences using OLS (I-IV) and Olley/Pakes (V-VIII) Productivities

Productivity in Domestic Manufacturing Firms and Reform in Upstream Services Sectors

Dependent Variable: TFP

I II III IV V VI VII VIII EBRD 0.777 0.689* 0.802 1.102* 0.887** 1.131* Services

Inputs

Linkage

[0.552] [0.401] [0.547] [0.580] [0.417] [0.572] FDI 2.315** 3.696* 3.873** 3.510* 2.237* 3.694* 4.263** 3.482*

(Threshold) [1.113] [1.878] [1.503] [1.768] [1.186] [1.963] [1.719] [1.832]

Privatization 3.697 4.841 9.106 10.409

[17.895] [16.648] [18.445] [17.025]

Concentration 1.451 1.551 1.551 1.765

[3.192] [3.095] [3.144] [3.105]

FDI 0.428 0.469 0.444 0.411 0.506 0.532 0.538 0.466 Manufacturing

Inputs

Linkage

(Threshold) [0.359] [0.327] [0.402] [0.383] [0.428] [0.394] [0.462] [0.443] Tariffs -0.194 -0.226 -0.223* -0.211 -0.199 -0.23 -0.238 -0.214

[0.126] [0.128] [0.129] [0.127] [0.138] [0.139] [0.144] [0.141]

FDI -0.212 -0.225* -0.214 -0.194 -0.216 -0.218 -0.224 -0.182 Competition

within sector

(Threshold) [0.126] [0.109] [0.157] [0.145] [0.145] [0.124] [0.168] [0.155] Tariffs 0.088 0.103* 0.099 0.098 0.092 0.107 0.112 0.103

[0.059] [0.059] [0.069] [0.058] [0.066] [0.066] [0.067] [0.067]

Dummies Industry FE

Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Region FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes R 2 0.052 0.055 0.053 0.053 0.055 0.055 0.055 0.053

N

2451 2451 2451 2451 2451 2451 2451 2451 The Inputs Linkage variables are weighted by the respective I/O coefficient. All regressors are differenced one year and then lagged one year. Standard errors in brackets are robust and clustered on industries. *, **, *** indicate statistical significance at the 10, 5 and 1% level.

Our findings of a positive relationship between liberalization of services sectors, and in particular opening of services sectors to foreign providers, and downstream manufacturing performance are consistent with a productivity-enhancing effect of a reform in services. They suggest that manufacturing firms relying more on inputs from liberalized services sectors or purchasing inputs from foreign services providers tend to exhibit higher total factor productivity. These findings are robust to controlling for several kinds of fixed effects, for changes in other aspects of liberalization and for systematic difference in performance growth across industries, years and regions.

7 Conclusions

In this paper, we create measures of reform in services sectors and combine them with information on the degree to which manufacturing firms rely on intermediate inputs from services industries. This allows us to analyze the relationship between services liberalization and downstream manufacturing performance. We capture services liberalization in four ways: (i) using a index of policy reforms created by the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD) taking into account all aspects of services liberalization, including both the domestic and the international dimension; (ii) considering the share of services output provided by foreign-

owned firms; (iii) focusing on the share of services provided by privatized firms; and (iv) considering the extent of competition in services sectors.

Our results suggest two conclusions. First, we find that services policy matters for manufacturing performance as we document a strong correlation between services sector reform and productivity of local producers relying on services as intermediate inputs. This evidence is robust to several different econometric specifications, including controls for firm, industry and region heterogeneity, for other aspects of openness, and for trend differences across industries and regions. Second, we find evidence suggesting that opening services sectors to foreign providers is a key channel through which services reforms affect downstream productivity in manufacturing.

As most barriers to foreign investment today are not in goods but in services, we hope that our findings will provide support for further liberalization of services industries and opening of services sectors to foreign providers.

相关文档