文档库 最新最全的文档下载
当前位置:文档库 › Oil Prices, Exhaustible Resources, and Economic Growth

Oil Prices, Exhaustible Resources, and Economic Growth

Oil Prices, Exhaustible Resources, and Economic Growth
Oil Prices, Exhaustible Resources, and Economic Growth

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES

OIL PRICES, EXHAUSTIBLE RESOURCES, AND ECONOMIC GROWTH

James D. Hamilton

Working Paper 17759

https://www.wendangku.net/doc/7717807520.html,/papers/w17759

NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH

1050 Massachusetts Avenue

Cambridge, MA 02138

January 2012

The views expressed herein are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research.

NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer-reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications.

? 2012 by James D. Hamilton. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including ? notice, is given to the source.

Oil Prices, Exhaustible Resources, and Economic Growth

James D. Hamilton

NBER Working Paper No. 17759

January 2012

JEL No. O40,Q30,Q41,Q43

ABSTRACT

This paper explores details behind the phenomenal increase in global crude oil production over the last century and a half and the implications if that trend should be reversed. I document that a key feature of the growth in production has been exploitation of new geographic areas rather than application of better technology to existing sources, and suggest that the end of that era could come soon. The economic dislocations that historically followed temporary oil supply disruptions are reviewed, and the possible implications of that experience for what the transition era could look like are explored. James D. Hamilton

Department of Economics, 0508

University of California, San Diego

9500 Gilman Drive

La Jolla, CA 92093-0508

and NBER

jhamilton@https://www.wendangku.net/doc/7717807520.html,

1Oil prices and the economics of resource exhaustion. One of the most elegant theories in economics is Hotelling’s(1931)characterization of the price of an exhaustible natural resource.From the perspective of overall social welfare, production today needs to be balanced against the consideration that,once consumed,the resource will be unavailable to future generations.One option for society would be to produce more of the commodity today,invest the current marginal bene?ts net of extraction costs in some other form of productive capital,and thereby accumulate bene?ts over time at the rate of interest earned on productive capital.An alternative is to save the resource so it can be used in the future.Optimal use of the resource over time calls for equating these two returns.This socially optimal plan could be implemented in a competitive equilibrium if the price of the resource net of marginal production cost rises at the rate of interest.For such a price path,the owner of the mine is just indi?erent between extracting a little bit more of the resource today or leaving it in the ground to be exploited at higher pro?t in the future.

This theory is compelling and elegant,but very hard to reconcile with the observed behavior of prices over the?rst century and a half of the oil industry.Figure1plots the real price of crude petroleum since1860.Oil has never been as costly as it was at the birth of the industry.Prior to Edwin Drake’s?rst oil well in Pennsylvania in1859,people were getting illuminants using very expensive methods.1The term kerosene,which we still use today to refer to a re?ned petroleum product,was actually a brand name used in the1850s for a liquid manufactured from asphalt or coal,a process which was then,as it still is now,

quite expensive.2Derrick’s Handbook(1898)reported that Drake had no trouble selling all the oil his well could produce in1859at a price of$20/barrel.Given the24-fold increase in estimates of consumer prices since1859,that would correspond to a price in2010dollars a little below$500/barrel.As drillers producing the new-found“rock oil”from other wells brought more of the product to the market,the price quickly fell,averaging$9.31/barrel for 1860(the?rst year shown in Figure1).In2010prices,that corresponds to$232a barrel, still far above anything seen subsequently.Even ignoring the initial half-century of the industry,the price of oil in real terms continued to drop from1900to1970.And despite episodes of higher prices in the1970s and2000s,throughout the period from1992-1999,the price of oil in real terms remained below the level reached in1920.

There are two traditional explanations for why Hotelling’s theory appears to be at odds with the long-run behavior of crude oil prices.The?rst is that although oil is in principle an exhaustible resource,in practice the supply has always been perceived to be so vast, and the date at which it will?nally be exhausted has been thought to be so far into the future,that?niteness of the resource had essentially no relevance for the current price.This interpretation could be reconciled with the Hotelling solution if one hypothesizes a tiny rent accruing to owners of the resource that indeed does grow at the rate of interest,but in practice has always been su?ciently small that the observed price is practically the same as the marginal extraction cost.

A second e?ort to save Hotelling’s theory appeals to the role of technological progress, which could lower marginal extraction costs(e.g.,Slade,1982),lead to discovery of new?elds

(Dasgupta and Heal,1979;Arrow and Chang,1982),or allow the exploitation of resources previously thought not to be economically accessible(Pindyck,1978).In generalizations of the Hotelling formulation,these can give rise to episodes or long periods in which the real price of oil is observed to fall,although eventually the price would begin to rise according to these models.Krautkraemer(1998)has a nice survey of theories of this type and examination of their empirical success at?tting the observed data.

Although it can sometimes be helpful to think about technological progress in broad, abstract terms,there is also much insight to be had from looking in some detail at the speci?c factors that allowed global oil production to increase almost without interruption over the last150years.For this purpose,I begin by examining some of the long-run trends in U.S.oil production.

1.1Oil production in the United States,1859-2010.

Certainly the technology for extracting oil from beneath the earth’s surface has evolved profoundly over time.Although Drake’s original well was steam-powered,some of the early drills were driven through rock by foot power,such as the spring-pole method.The workers would kick a heavy bit at the end of the rope down into the rock,and spring action from the compressed pole would lift the bit back up.After some time at this,the drill would be lifted out and a bucket lowered to bail out the debris.Of course subsequent years produced rapid advances over these?rst primitive e?orts—better sources of power, improved casing technology,and vastly superior knowledge of where oil might be found.

Other key innovations included the adoption of rotary drilling at the turn of the century, in which circulating?uid lifted debris out of the hole,and secondary recovery methods?rst developed in the1920s,in which water,air,or gas is injected into oil wells to repressurize the reservoir and allow more of the oil to be lifted to the surface.

Figure2plots the annual oil production levels for Pennsylvania and New York,where the industry began,from1862to2010.Production increased by a factor of10between 1862and1891.However,it is a mistake to view this as the result of application of better technology to the initially exploited?elds.Production from the original Oil Creek District in fact peaked in1874(Williamson and Daum,1959,p.378).The production gains instead came primarily from development of new?elds,most importantly the Bradford?eld near the Pennsylvania-New York border,but also from Butler,Clarion,and Armstrong Counties. Nevertheless,it is unquestionably the case that better drilling techniques than used in Oil Creek were necessary in order to reach the greater depths of the Bradford formation.

One also sees quite clearly in Figure2the bene?ts of the secondary recovery methods applied in the1920s,which succeeded in producing much additional oil from the Bradford formation and elsewhere in the state.However,it is worth noting that these methods never lifted production in Pennsylvania back to where it had been in1891.In2010—with the truly awesome technological advances of the century and a half since the industry began, and with the price of oil5times as high(in real terms)as it had been in1891—Pennsylvania and New York produced under4million barrels of crude oil.That’s only12%of what had been produced in1891—120years ago—and about the level that the sturdy farmers with

their spring-poles were getting out of the ground back in1868.

Although Pennsylvania was the most important source of U.S.oil production in the 19th century,the nation’s oil production continued to increase even after Pennsylvanian production peaked in1891.The reason is that later in the century,new sources of oil were also being obtained from neighboring West Virginia and Ohio(see Figure3).Production from these two states was rising rapidly even as production from Pennsylvania and New York started to fall.Ohio production would continue to rise before peaking in1896,and West Virginia did not peak until1900.

These four states together accounted for90%of U.S.production in1896,with the peak in production from the region as a whole coming that year(see Figure4).Overall U.S.pro-duction declined for a few years with falling supplies from Appalachia,but quickly returned to establishing new highs in1900,thanks to growth in production from new areas in the central United States,details of which are shown in Figure5.Note the di?erence in scale, with the vertical axes in Figure5spanning6times the magnitude of corresponding axes in Figure3.Each of the regions featured in Figure5would eventually produce far more oil than Appalachia ever did.These areas began producing much later than Appalachia,and each peaked much later than Appalachia.The combined production of Illinois and Indiana peaked in1940,Kansas-Nebraska in1957,the southwest in1960,and Wyoming in1970.

Far more important for U.S.total production were the four states shown in Figure6, which uses a vertical scale2.5times that for Figure5.California,Oklahoma,Texas,and Louisiana account for70%of all the oil ever produced in the United States.Production

from Oklahoma reached a peak in1927,though it was still able to produce at80%of that level as recently as1970before entering a modern phase of decline that now leaves it at25% of the1927production levels.Texas managed to grow its oil production until1972,and today produces about a third of what it did then.California production continued to grow until1985before peaking.The graph for Louisiana(bottom panel of Figure6)includes all the U.S.production from the Gulf of Mexico,growing production from which helped bring the state’s indicated production for2010up to a value only33%below its peak in1971.

Figure7plots production histories for the two regions whose development began latest in U.S.history.Production from Alaska peaked in1988.North Dakota is the only state that continues to set all-time records for production,thanks in part to use of new drilling techniques for recovering oil from shale formations.To put the new Williston Basin produc-tion in perspective,the138million barrels produced in North Dakota and Montana in2010 is about half of what the state of Oklahoma produced in1927and a?fth of what the state of Alaska produced in1988.However,the potential for these?elds looks very promising and further signi?cant increases from2010levels seems assured.

The experience for the U.S.thus admits a quite clear summary.Production from every state has followed a pattern of initial increase followed by eventual decline.The feature that nonetheless allowed the total production for the U.S.to exhibit a seemingly uninterrupted upward trend over the course of a century was the fact that new,more promising areas were always coming into production at the same time that mature?elds were dying out(see Figure8).Total U.S.production continued to grow before peaking in1970,long after the

original?elds in Appalachia and the central U.S.were well into decline.

And the decline in production from both individual regions within the U.S.as well as the United States as a whole has come despite phenomenal improvements in technology over time.Production from the Gulf of Mexico has made a very important contribution to slowing the rate of decline over the most recent decade.Some of this production today is coming from wells that begin a mile below sea level and bore from there through up to a half-dozen more miles of rock—try doing that with three guys kicking a spring-pole down!The decline in U.S.production has further come despite aggressive drilling in very challenging environments and widespread adoption of secondary and now tertiary recovery methods.The rise and fall of production from individual states seems much more closely related to discoveries of new?elds and their eventual depletion than to the sorts of price incentives or technological innovations on which economists are accustomed to focus.

Notwithstanding,technological improvements continue to bring signi?cant new?elds into play.The most important recent development has been horizontal rather than verti-cal drilling through hydrocarbon-bearing formations accompanied by injection of?uids to induce small fractures in the rock.These methods have allowed access to hydrocarbons trapped in rock whose permeability or depth prevented removal using traditional methods. The new methods have enabled phenomenal increases in supplies of natural gas as well as signi?cant new oil production in areas such as North Dakota and Texas.Wickstrom,et.al. (2011)speculated that application of hydraulic fracturing to the Utica Shale formation in Ohio might eventually produce several billion barrels of oil,which would be more than the

cumulative production from the state up to this point.If that indeed turns out to be the case,it could lead to a third peak in the graphs in Figure3for the Appalachian region that exceeds either of the?rst two,though for comparison the projected lifetime output from Utica would still only correspond to a few years of production from Texas at that state’s peak.

Obviously price incentives and technological innovations matter a great deal.More oil will be brought to the surface at a price of$100a barrel than at$10a barrel,and more oil can be produced with the new technology than with the old.But it seems a mistake to overstate the operative elasticities.By1960,the real price of oil had fallen to a level that was1/3its value in1900.Over the same period,U.S.production of crude oil grew to become55times what it had been in1900.On the other hand,the real price of oil rose8-fold from1970to2010,while U.S.production of oil fell by43%over those same40 years.The increase in production from1900to1960thus could in no way be attributed to the response to price incentives.Likewise,neither huge price incentives nor impressive technological improvements were su?cient to prevent the decline in production from1970to 2010.Further exploitation of o?shore or deep shale resources may help put U.S.production back on an upward trend for the next decade,but it seems unlikely ever again to reach the levels seen in1970.

1.2W orld oil production,1973-2010.

Despite the peak in U.S.production in1970,world oil production was to grow to a level in 2010that is60%higher than it had been in1970.The mechanics of this growth are the same as allowed total U.S.production to continue to increase long after production from the initial areas entered into decline—increases from new?elds in other countries more than o?set the declines from the United States.For example,the North Sea and Mexico accounted for only1%of world production in1970,but had grown to13%of total world output by1999. But production from the North Sea peaked in that year,and in2010is only at54%of the peak level(see Figure9).Cantarell,which is Mexico’s main producing?eld,also appears to have passed peak production,with the country now at75%of its2004oil production.

Production from members of the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries(OPEC) must be interpreted from a much di?erent perspective.The episodes of declining production one sees in the bottom panel of Figure10have little to do with geological depletion but instead often re?ect dramatic geopolitical events such as the OPEC embargo of1973-74, the Iranian revolution in1978-1979,the Iranian revolution and beginning of the Iran-Iraq War1978-1981,and the?rst Persian Gulf war in1990-91,events that will be reviewed in more detail in the following section.In addition,Saudi Arabia in particular(top panel)has often made a deliberate decision to increase or decrease production in an e?ort to mitigate price increases or decreases.For example,Saudi Arabia cut production to try to hold up prices during the weak oil market1981-85and recession of2001,and boosted production to make up for output lost from other producing countries during the two Persian Gulf

wars.However,the decline in Saudi Arabian production since2005would have to be attributed to di?erent considerations from those that explain the earlier historical data.The kingdom’s magni?cent Ghawar?eld has been in production since1951,and in recent years had accounted for perhaps6%of total world production all by itself.There is considerable speculation that Ghawar may have peaked,though this is di?cult to con?rm.What we do know is that,for whatever reason,Saudi Arabia produced600,000fewer barrels each day in 2010than it did in2005,and with growing Saudi consumption of their own oil,the drop in exports from Saudi Arabia has been even more dramatic.

A mix of factors has clearly also contributed to stagnating production from other OPEC members over the last5years.Promising new?elds in Angola have allowed that country to double its production since2003.In Nigeria and Iraq,con?icts and unrest have held back what appears to be promising geological potential.In Venezuela and Iran,it is hard to know how much more might be produced with better functioning governments.But again, although there is a complicated mix of di?erent factors at work in di?erent countries,the bottom line is that the total production from OPEC has essentially been?at since2005.

At the same time,some other countries continue to register increases in oil production (see Figure11).China has doubled its oil production since1982,though its three most important?elds(Daqing,Shengli,and Liaohe)peaked in the mid1990s(Kambara and Howe,2007).Canadian oil production continues to increase as a result of the contribution of oil sands.Unfortunately,exploitation of this resource is far more costly in terms of capital and energy inputs and environmental externalities relative to conventional sources,

and it is di?cult to see it ever accounting for a major fraction of total world oil production. Other regions such as Brazil,central Asia,and Africa have also seen signi?cant gains in oil production(bottom panel of Figure11).Overall,global production of oil from all sources was essentially constant from2005to2010(see Figure12).

1.3Reconciling historical experience with the theory of exhaustible

resources.

The evidence from the preceding subsections can be summarized as follows.When one looks at individual oil-producing regions,one does not see a pattern of continuing increases as a result of ongoing technological progress.Instead there has inevitably been an initial gain as key new?elds were developed followed by subsequent decline.Technological progress and the incentives of higher prices can temporarily reverse that decline,as was seen for example in the impressive resurgence of Pennsylvanian production in the1920s.In recent years these same factors have allowed U.S.production to grow rather than decline,and that trend in the U.S.may continue for some time.However,these factors have historically appeared to be distinctly secondary to the broad reality that after a certain period of exploitation,annual ?ow rates of production from a given area are going to start to decline.Those encouraged by the10%increase in U.S.oil production between2008and2010should remember that the level of U.S.production in2010is still25%below where it had been in1990(when the real price of oil was half of what it is today)and43%below the level of1970(when the real price of oil was1/8of what it is today).

Some may argue that the peaking of production from individual areas is governed by quite di?erent economic considerations than would apply to the?nal peaking of total production from all world sources combined.Certainly in an environment in which the market is pricing oil as an essentially inexhaustible resource,the pattern of peaking documented extensively above is perfectly understandable,given that so far there have always been enough new ?elds somewhere in the world to take the place of declining production from mature regions. One could also reason that,even if the price of oil has historically been following some kind of Hotelling path,?elds with di?erent marginal extraction costs would logically be developed at di?erent times.Smith(2011)further noted that,according to the Hotelling model,the date at which global production peaks would be determined endogenously by the cumulative amount that could eventually be extracted and the projected time path for the demand function.His analysis suggests that the date for an eventual peak in global oil production should be determined by these economic considerations rather than the engineering mechanics that have produced the historical record for individual regions detailed above.

However,my reading of the historical evidence is as follows.(1)For much of the history of the industry,oil has been priced essentially as if it were an inexhaustible resource.(2) Although technological progress and enhanced recovery techniques can temporarily boost production?ows from mature?elds,it is not reasonable to view these factors as the primary determinants of annual production rates from a given?eld.(3)The historical source of increasing global oil production is exploitation of new geographical areas,a process whose

promise at the global level is obviously limited.The combined implication of these three observations is that,at some point there will need to be a shift in how the price of oil is determined,with considerations of resource exhaustion playing a bigger role than they have historically.

A factor accelerating the date of that transition is the phenomenal growth of demand for oil from the emerging economies.Eight emerging economies—Brazil,China,Hong Kong, India,Singapore,South Korea,Taiwan,and Thailand—accounted for43%of the increase in world petroleum consumption between1998and2005and for135%of the increase between 2005and2010(the rest of the world decreased its petroleum consumption over the latter period in response to the big increase in price).3And,as Hamilton(2009a)noted,one could easily imagine the growth in demand from the emerging economies continuing.One has only to compare China’s one passenger vehicle per30residents today with the one vehicle per1.3residents seen in the United States,or China’s2010annual petroleum consumption of2.5barrels per person with Mexico’s6.7or the United States’22.4.Even if the world sees phenomenal success in?nding new sources of oil over the next decade,it could prove quite challenging to keep up with both depletion from mature?elds and rapid growth in demand from the emerging economies,another reason to conclude that the era in which petroleum is regarded as an essentially unlimited resource has now ended.

Some might infer that the decrease in Saudi Arabian production since2005re?ects not an inability to maintain production?ows from the mature Ghawar?eld but instead is a deliberate response to recognition of a growing importance of the scarcity rent.For example,

Hamilton(2009a)noted the following story on April13,2008from Reuters news service: Saudi Arabia’s King Abdullah said he had ordered some new oil discoveries left

untapped to preserve oil wealth in the world’s top exporter for future generations,

the o?cial Saudi Press Agency(SPA)reported.

“I keep no secret from you that when there were some new?nds,I told them,

‘no,leave it in the ground,with grace from God,our children need it’,”King

Abdullah said in remarks made late on Saturday,SPA said.

If that is indeed the interpretation,it is curious that we would see the private optimizing choices predicted by Hotelling manifest by sovereign governments rather than the?elds under control of private oil companies.In any case,it must be acknowledged that calculation of the correct Hotelling price is almost insurmountably di?cult.It is hard enough for the best forecasters accurately to predict supply and demand for the coming year.But the critical calculation required by Hotelling is to evaluate the transversality condition that the resource be exhausted when the price reaches that of a backstop technology or alternatively over the in?nite time horizon if no such backstop exists.That calculation is orders of magnitudes more di?cult than the seemingly simpler task of just predicting next year’s supply and demand.

One could argue that the combined decisions of the many participants in world oil markets can make a better determination of what the answer to the above calculation should be than can any individual,meaning that if the current price seems inconsistent with a scenario in which global oil production will soon reach a peak,then such a scenario is perhaps not

the most likely outcome.But saying that the implicit judgment from the market is the best guess available is not the same thing as saying that this guess is going to prove to be correct.The historical record surely dictates that we take seriously the possibility that the world could soon reach a point from which a continuous decline in the annual?ow rate of production could not be avoided,and inquire whether the transition to a pricing path consistent with that reality could prove to be a fairly jarring event.For this reason,it seems worthwhile to review the historical record on the economic response to previous episodes in which the price or supply of oil changed dramatically,to which we now turn in the next section.

2Oil prices and economic growth.

2.1Historical oil price shocks.

There have been a number of episodes over the last half century in which con?icts in the Middle East have led to signi?cant disruptions in production of crude oil.These include closure of the Suez Canal following the con?ict between Egypt,Israel,Britain,and France in October1956,the oil embargo implemented by the Arab members of OPEC following the Arab-Israeli War in October1973,the Iranian revolution beginning in November1978,the Iran-Iraq War beginning in September of1980,and the?rst Persian Gulf war beginning in August1990.Figure13summarizes the consequences of these5events for world oil supplies. In each panel,the solid line displays the drop in production from the a?ected areas expressed

as a percentage of total world production prior to the crisis.In each episode,there were some o?setting increases in production elsewhere in the world.The dashed lines in Figure 13indicate the magnitude of the actual decline in total global production following each event,again expressed as a fraction of world production.Each of these5episodes was followed by a decrease in world oil production of4-9%.

There have also been some other more minor supply disruptions over this period.These include the combined e?ects of the second Persian Gulf war and strikes in Venezuela be-ginning in December2002,and the Libyan revolution in February2011.The disruption in supply associated with either of these episodes was about2%of total global production at the time,or less than a third the size of the average event in Figure13.

There are other episodes since World War II when the price of oil rose abruptly in the absence of a signi?cant physical disruption in the supply of oil.Most notable of these would be the broad upswing in the price of oil beginning in2004,which accelerated sharply in 2007.The principal cause of this oil spike appears to have been strong demand for oil from the emerging economies confronting the stagnating global production levels documented in the previous sections(see Kilian,2008,2009,Hamilton,2009b and Kilian and Hicks,2011). Less dramatic price increases followed the economic recovery from the East Asian Crisis in1997,dislocations associated with post World War II growth in1947,and the Korean con?ict in1952-53.Table1summarizes a series of historical episodes discussed in Hamilton (forthcoming[b]).It is interesting that of the11episodes listed,10of these were followed by a recession in the United States.The recession of1960is the only U.S.postwar recession

that was not preceded by a spike in the price of crude oil.

A large empirical literature has investigated the connection between oil prices and real economic growth.Early studies documenting a statistically signi?cant negative correlation include Rasche and Tatom(1977,1981)and Santini(1985).Empirical analysis of dynamic forecasting regressions found that oil price changes could help improve forecasts of U.S.real output growth(Hamilton,1983;Burbidge and Harrison,1984;Gisser and Goodwin,1986). However,these speci?cations,which were based on linear relations between the log change in oil prices and the log of real output growth,broke down when the dramatic oil price decreases of the mid-1980s were not followed by an economic boom.On the contrary,the mid-1980s appeared to be associated with recession conditions in the oil-producing states(Hamilton and Owyang,forthcoming).Mork(1989)found a much better?t to a model that allowed for oil price decreases to have a di?erent e?ect on the economy from oil price increases,though Hooker(1996)demonstrated that this modi?cation still had trouble describing subsequent data.Other papers?nding a signi?cant connection between oil price increases and poor economic performance include Santini(1992,1994),Rotemberg and Woodford(1996),Daniel (1997),and Carruth,Hooker and Oswald(1998).

Alternative nonlinear dynamic relations seem to have a signi?cantly better?t to U.S. data than Mork’s simple asymmetric formulation.Loungani(1986)and Davis(1987a, 1987b)found that oil price decreases could actually reduce economic growth,consistent with the claim that sectorial reallocations could be an important part of the economic transmission mechanism resulting from changes in oil prices in either direction.Ferderer

(1996),Elder and Serletis(2010),and Jo(2011)showed that an increase in oil price volatility itself tends to predict slower GDP growth,while Lee,Ni,and Ratti(1995)found that oil price increases seem to a?ect the economy less if they occur following an episode of high volatility.Hamilton(2003)estimated a?exible nonlinear form and found evidence for a threshold e?ect,in which an oil price increase that simply reverses a previous decrease seems to have little e?ect on the economy.Hamilton(1996),Raymond and Rich(1997),Davis and Haltiwanger(2001)and Balke,Brown and Yücel(2002)produced evidence in support of related speci?cations,while Carlton(2010)and Ravazzolo and Rothman(2010)reported that the Hamilton(2003)speci?cation performed well in an out-of-sample forecasting exercise using data as it would have been available in real time.Kilian and Vigfusson(forthcoming [a])found weaker(though still statistically signi?cant)evidence of nonlinearity than reported by other researchers.Hamilton(forthcoming[a])attributed their weaker evidence to use of a shorter data set and changes in speci?cation from other researchers.

A negative e?ect of oil prices on real output has also been reported for a number of other countries,particularly when nonlinear functional forms have been employed.Mork,Olsen and Mysen(1994)found that oil price increases were followed by reductions in real GDP growth in6of the7OECD countries investigated,the one exception being the oil exporter Norway.Cu?ado and Pérez de Gracia(2003)found a negative correlation between oil prices changes and industrial production growth rates in13out of14European economies,with a nonlinear function of oil prices making a statistically signi?cant contribution to forecast growth rates for11of these.Jiménez-Rodríguez and Sánchez(2005)found a statistically

红外测油仪选购指南

红外测油仪选购指南 本文不是为任何厂家做广告,只是把本人这些年选购红外测油仪的心得体会告诉大家,为你选购时做个参考。 怎样才能选购一台质量可靠、服务到位的红外测油仪? 1、网上搜索,仅供参考 上网搜索“红外测油仪”关键词,铺天盖地的红外测油仪广告扑面而来,让人无所适从,你一定会选择排名靠前的厂商吧,别急,不妨多花点时间往后翻翻页,多看几家。 网上的排名与产品质量和服务毫无关系,那为什么排名靠前,原因你懂的。 记录这些厂商的联系方式,一家一家地慢慢甄别,这当然要花费一点时间。 2、识别真正的生产厂家 别看网上的广告成百上千,真正的有能力研发和生产这俩仪器的厂家,据我所知, 不超过10家,其余的是经销商或贴牌商。怎样才能识别真正的厂家呢,我的办法是: ①:看这个厂家经营的品种 一个研发和生产测油仪的厂家,有两三个或四五个系列产品,就已经很不错了,而且产品相关度很高,如果这个厂家所经营的产品品种多样,五花八门,多半不是自己研发的。 ②:看生产许可证 红外测油仪属于计量仪器,理论上应该取得相关计量部门核发的生产许可证,如下图的型式批准证书。这个证书是强制的,必须有的,是产品质量的保证。 ③:看软件著作权证书 软件著作权证书并不是强制执行的,生产厂家也不一定非得去申请这个证书,但是,如果有,至少可以说明这个仪器的软件是这个厂家自己开发的。是有一定的研发能力的。 ④:直接到厂参观。 百闻不如一见,有条件的用户应该直接到生产厂家考察,是不是厂家,一看便知。真正的生产厂家是不会拒绝客户参观的。即使真没有条件去,也应该在提出去 厂里参观的要求,看看对方是不是很为难。 3、要求上门安装 厂家必须承诺能上门安装,直到验收合格。如果不能上门安装,那一定是厂家没有底气,有些厂家的仪器安装工程师,上门安装时,因产品不过关,几天也脱不了身,这样的产品,你敢用吗? 4、仪器谱图玄机多 红外测油仪在测量过程中,必须显示谱图,这是国标中规定的。不管是台式红外测油仪还是全自动红外测油仪。通过观察谱图可以发现很多问题:

最常用日常英语口语句型100句

最常用日常英语口语句型100句 1. I'm an office worker. 我是上班族。 2. I work for the government. 我在政府机关做事。 3. I'm happy to meet you. 很高兴见到你。 4. I like your sense of humor. 我喜欢你的幽默感。 5. I'm glad to see you again. 很高兴再次见到你。 6. I'll call you. 我会打电话给你。 7. I feel like sleeping. 我想睡会儿。 8. I want something to eat. 我想吃点东西。 9. I need your help. 我需要你的帮助。 10. I would like to talk to you for a minute. 我想和你谈一下。 11. I have a lot of problems. 我有很多问题。 12. I hope our dreams come true. 我希望我们的梦想成真。 13. I'm looking forward to seeing you. 我期望见到你。 14. I'm supposed to go on a diet. 我应该节食。 15. I heard that you're getting married. Congratulations.听说你要结婚了,恭喜! 16. I see what your mean. 我了解你的意思。

17. I can't do this. 我不能这么做。 18. Let me explain why I was late. 让我解释迟到的理由。 19. Let's have a beer or something. 咱们喝点啤酒什么的。 20. Where is your office? 你们的办公室在哪? 21. What is your plan? 你的计划是什么? 22. When is the store closing? 这家店什么时候结束营业? 23. Are you sure you can come by at nine? 你肯定你九点能来吗? 24. Am I allowed to stay out past 10? 我可以十点过后再回家吗? 25. The meeting was scheduled for two hours, but it is not over yet. 会议原定了两个小时,不过现在还没有结束。 26. Tom's birthday is this week. 汤姆的生日就在这个星期。 27. Would you care to sit down for a while? 你要不要坐一会呢? 28. Can you cover for me on Friday? 星期五能不能请你替我个班? 29. Could you do me a big favor? 能否请你帮我个忙? 30. He is crazy about Friends. 他对《老友记》很着迷。 31. Can you imagine how much he paid for that car?你能想象他买那车花了多少钱吗?

必备英语口语简单句

易说堂英语必备口语简单句 1. Excuse me. [翻译] 打扰一下/不好意思。 [解析] 初到国外,问路,问时间等等各种事情,这句话是必备的;另外,当你在拥挤的步行街穿越时,这句话也是必须挂在嘴边的。 2. I am a new student. My name is … [翻译] 我是一位新同学,我的名字是… [解析] 去警局、银行、学校注册时,用来说明自己的身份。 3. Nice to meet you! [翻译] 很高兴认识你! [解析] 认识新朋友必备的第一句话。 4. That's a lovely hat! [翻译] 这个帽子真可爱! [解析] 西方人非常懂得赞美,在商店,在超市,礼品店你随处都可以听到他们并非客套的赞美。 5. What's the matter? [翻译] 怎么了?

[解析] 这是破冰的一种非常好的方式。当你对某件事情或者某人的境遇特别好奇的时候,可以用上这句话。 6. Are you all right? [翻译] 你还好吧? [解析] 生活中总有磕磕绊绊,当你看到别人眉头紧皱,或者面色难看时,可以用这句话进行询问。另外,all right在英国很多时候表示go ahead. 7. Give me a book please, Jane. [翻译] 简,请递给我一本书。 [解析] 非常简单的句子,在图书馆,教室请别人递给自己东西时脱口而出。 8. There is a refrigerator in the kitchen. [翻译] 在厨房里有一个冰箱。 [解析] 在给别人介绍自己家的物品或者某处风景的时候,都可以用上。 9. Where is it? [翻译] 在哪? [解析] 可以直接用where来提问。 10. What must I do? [翻译] 有什么必须要做的?

常用的英语口语句型

常用的英语口语句型 浏览:364|更新:2013-06-06 16:10 1. According to…依照/根据…….According to the newspaper, it's a great movie.根据报纸说,这是一部很棒的电影. 2. Am I allowed to…我可以……吗Am I allowed to introduce our new manager Mr. Anderson to all of you请允许我介绍我们的新经理安德森先生给大家,好吗 3. As matter of fact,…实际上……,…….As matter of fact,I don't agree with you.实际上,我不大同意你的看法. 4.As far as I'm concerned/…就我而言,…….As far as I'm concerned, | think we should pay more attention to the safety ofschoolchildren.就我而言,我认为我们应该更关注在校儿童的安全问题. 5.As far as I know,...据我所知,…….As far as l know,he is not coming,but l may be wrong.据我所知,他不打算来,但我或许会弄错. 6.As I just mentioned...正如我刚才提到过的,…….As I just mentioned, nobody should drop out of school unless they believe theyface the opportunity of a lifetime. And even then they should reconsider.正如我刚才提到过的,任何人都不应该辍学,除非他们相信他们面临着一生中难得的机会,尽管那样,他们还需反复思量. 7. As I see it,…在我看来,…….As I see it, he is not the right person for this position. 在我看来,他不是这个职位的合适人选. 8. As is known to us all, ...众所周知,……As is known to us all, Hong Kong is one of the financial centers of Asia.众所周知,香港是亚洲金融中心之一. 9. As long as...只要….As long as we work together, we can make the impossible possible.只要我们一起努力,我们就能把不可能变为可能. 10.But for...若不是因为……./如果没有…….But for your generous help, we couldn't have finished the work so soon.如果没有你的鼎力相助,我们不可能这么快完成工作的. 11.Can you believe (that)...你相信……吗Can you believe (that) this excellent song was composed by a high schoolstudent你相信这首美妙的歌曲是出自一个高中生之手吗 12.Can you imagine...你能想像……吗Can you imagine how she lived through all these difficulties你能想像她是怎么捱过种种困难的吗 13.Could you please explain...你能解释一下……吗Could you please explain why you didn't come to the meeting yesterday你能解释一下为什么昨天没来开会吗

红外分光测油仪产品简介

JC-OIL-6A型数显红外测油仪既能进行红外分光光度法、非分散红外光度法对油份浓度的测定,也可扫描样品光谱图,作为近红外光谱仪使用。满足环保部门对地下水、地表水、生活污水和工业废水中石油类和动植物油含量及餐饮业油烟浓度的测定要求。是目前国内广泛推广的测油仪器。用四氯化碳萃取水中的油类物质,测定总萃取物,然后将萃取液用硅酸镁吸附,经脱除动植物油等极性物质后,测定石油类。总萃取物和石油类的含量均由波数分别为2930cm-1(CH2基团中C-H键的伸缩振动)、2960cm-1(CH3基团中C-H键的伸缩振动)和3030cm-1(芳香环中C-H键的伸缩振动)谱带处的吸光度A2930、A2960和A3030进行计算。动植物油的含量按总萃取物与石油类含量之差计算。 JC-OIL-6A数显型红外分光测油仪产品参数 1、测量范围:0.1~100mg/L(4cm比色皿萃取液中油浓度);0.001~10000mg/L(4cm 比色皿水样中油浓度) 2、线性相关系数:R>0.999 3、检出限:0.1mg/L(萃取液) 4、*低检出浓度:0.001mg/L(水样1:100萃取) 5、测量准确度:±2% 6、测量重复性:1% 7、波数范围:4000cm-1~2400 cm-1 8、波数分辨率:0.2 cm-1 9、波数准确度:±1 cm-1 10、波数重复性:1 cm-1 11、电源及功耗:AC220V±10% ,50Hz ,40VA

12、外形尺寸:480×310×150(mm)净重:12Kg 13、控制方式:内置单片机或通过USB接口连接台式电脑或笔记本电脑 JC-OIL-6A型数显型红外分光测油仪产品特点 1、真正的红外分光三波数测油仪,全面考察油品中CH2基团中C-H键的伸缩振动(由2930cm-1测定)、CH3基团中C-H键的伸缩振动(由2960cm-1测定)和芳香环中C-H键的伸缩振动(由3030cm-1测定),测量结果不受油品组份变化的影响。 2、无需制作标准曲线,无需调零点、调满度,无需定标,可直接测量样品。 3、可采用一只比色皿,消除了比色皿之间的差异对测量结果的影响,测量精度更高,采用多只比色皿时,设有比色皿数据库,具有保存比色皿数据,自动扣除比色皿背景的功能。 4、长寿命光源,无需更换光源。 5、调制光源,信号频率高,选频放大,信号输出不受杂散光影响。 6、采用精密步进电机控制光栅,具有波长自动修正功能,波长精度高,重复性好。 7、采用半导体探测器,使用寿命长,应用半导体致冷技术,使信号输出更稳定,信号输出不受室温变化的影响。 8、功能强大:具有红外分光光度法、非分散红外光度法,光谱扫描等多种功能,扫描范围宽,可作为红外光谱仪使用。 9、具有光源自动补偿系统、信号漂移修正系统,基线无漂移。 10、内置单片机控制,液晶显示,可完全脱离电脑独立工作。也可通过USB接口连接电脑控制主机,功能完善,操作简便。 11、在同一桌面上,同时显示光谱图、测量步骤、测量结果,在光谱图中可以读出光谱任一点的波数位置、吸光度和透射比。

英语口语必备动词

,. 口语必备动词短语 ● 1.动词+about speak/talk about谈论think about思考 care about关心,对...有兴趣bring about引起,使发生set about 着手,开始 come about发生 hear about听说 worry about为...担心 2.动词+away throw away 扔掉 blow away吹走 carry away拿走,使入迷clear away清除掉,消散die away逐渐消失 pass away 去世 wash away冲走 take away拿走 put away收拾起来,存起来give away背弃,泄露 wear away磨掉,消耗break away摆脱 send away让走开 turn away把...打发走 3.动词+back keep back隐瞒,忍住 hold back控制住 call back回电话 look back回顾 give back归还 take back拿回,收回 4.动词+for run for竞选 ask for要求得到 wait for等候 long for渴望 care for关心,喜欢 search for查找 call for要求,需要change for用...换 apply for申请 seek for寻找stand for代表,表示 hope/wish for希望得到beg for乞求 look for寻找 hunt for寻找 charge for收费,要价 take for误以为...是 come for来拿,来取 5.动词+down burn down 烧毁 take down记下,记录 cut down削减,砍倒 pass down 传下来 calm down平静下来 settle down 安家 tear down 拆毁,拆除break down坏了,垮了,分解turn down调小,拒绝 slow down慢下来 put down记下,写下,镇压bring down使...降低,使倒下come down下落,传下 6.动词+at come at 向...袭击 run at冲向,向...攻击 tear at用力撕 stare at凝视 glance at匆匆一瞥 knock at敲门,窗等 smile at冲某人笑 aim at向...瞄准 wonder at惊讶 shout at冲某人嚷嚷 work at干...活动研究 look at看,注视 glare at怒视 laugh at嘲笑 point at指向 strike at向...打击 shoot at向...射击 call at拜访地点 7.动词+from differ from与...不同 suffer from受...苦

英语口语常用句式

我可以……吗 常用句子:May I come in 我可以进来吗 May I help you 您需要帮忙吗 May I ask you a question 我可以问你一个问题吗 搭配:接动词原型。 } 例句:May I speak to Vincent 请问文森在吗 May I use your telephone 我可以借用你的电话吗 May I have a seat 我可以坐下吗 功能: 用这些话显得很有教养。 2. Can you … ? 你能……吗 常用句子:Can you help me 你能帮帮我吗 Can you do me a favor 你能帮我个忙吗 Can you please tell me where is the bus stop 你能告诉我公共汽车站怎么走吗 搭配:接动词原型。 — 例句:Can you please shut the door 你能把门关上吗 Can you translate the sentence into Chinese for me 你能帮我把这个句子翻译成中文吗 Can you lend me some money 你能借我点钱吗 功能:用于比较熟悉的人之间,会让对方感觉亲切。如果想再客 气一点,可以把can换成could。 > 3. I’d like to … 我想…… 常用句子:I’d like to have a self-introduction. 我想作个自我介绍。 I’d like to talk about the matter. 我想谈谈那件事。 I’d like to have a cup of tea. 我想喝杯茶。 、 搭配:加动词原型。 例句:I’d like to book a double-room.

红外分光测油十大误区

“红外分光测油仪”十大误区 采用“红外分光光度法”测量环境中油污染的数据,具有全球可比性高、灵敏度高、抗干扰性强、测量矿物油结果不受油品变化影响,被许多国家所采纳。虽然我国现有“红外分光测油仪”的普及率也较高,但是在市场经济的冲击下,“红外分光测油仪”已经很难看出原来的面目了。我国“红外分光测油仪”发明人何秉站曾经讲过:“研制生产‘红外分光测油仪’的目的就是要统一我国测油的标准方法,提高测量结果的可比性”,而如今市场上纷杂的“红外分光测油仪”使测量油污染的数据五花八门,根本没有可比性。由于采用“红外分光光度法”测量环境中油污染,是一项比较专业的测量技术,这方面的专家、书籍较少,更有许多技术、理论不完善。根据十几年的研究,谈谈我们的看法,让人们来评论,希望能实现发明人的愿望,真正的统一我国测油的标准方法。 误区1:有人认为同样都是红外分光测油仪,原理一样都能用。 根据近期调查,我国各个厂家生产的“红外分光测油仪”对油品的测量结果误差太大,谈不上可比性,人们的想象和现实相差遥远。“红外分光测油仪”是由光、机、电、计算机等综合技术组成,就仪器本身的结构差别,实验室工作人员多会混淆。至于哪些技术是创新的,哪些技术是仿制的,我们暂不研究。可是有一条,我们是必须知道的,那就是用“红外分光光度法”测量油的计算公式: C=A2930*X+A2960*Y+Z*(A3030-A2930/F) C -------- 油的浓度值; A2930、A2960、A3030 -------- 分别是CH2、CH3、CH的波数的吸光度 X、Y、Z、F -------- 是仪器校正系数(一般由厂家给出) 由于国标没有涉及仪器校正系数如何具体计算,于是一些仪器厂家采用标油测量后重复调整系数值,直到满意为止,这种做法是没有科学依据的。这种做法的不科学性带来的问题是测量结果随着油品的变化而变化,造成了测量结果无可比性的严重问题。计算仪器校正系数有一套完整的计算公式,比国标的计算浓度值要复杂得多。为了推导、证明计算仪器校正系数公式的正确性,用计算机计算的数据多达2000页,并不是用标液调整就行的事。仪器校正系数是仪器的核心技术,如同计算机里的操作系统,这就是采用不一致的“红外分光测油仪”测量结果没有可比性的根本原因。有些人认为测量标油的结果误差不大,仪器就可以使用,这只是错误的理解了“红外分光光度法测量油品的基本特征,测量结果不受油品变化影响”的原则性问题。由于标油的油品结构是不变的,用同样结构的标样测量同样结构的另一标样,当然误差不大(有些厂家便是根据这个标样,调整出仪器的校正系数)。如果变化油品之后再进行测量,例如测量20mg/L 异辛烷或100mg/L 苯,它们的误差就会大的惊人。所以,只有能推导、证明出计算仪器校正系数公式的单位,才有资格生产“红外分光测油仪”。因为这方面的计量认证工作还不够规范,也造成了今天各类产品测量结果没有可比性的事实。目前,只有【吉林北光】(即“红外分光测油仪”的发明单位)可正确计算出仪器的校正系数X、Y、Z、F值。 误区2:都是红外测油仪,测量结果有没有谱图都一样。 在环境监测中,我们会遇到许许多多奇怪的干扰物,尤其是测油项目,受到干扰因数特别多,即使是由于萃取后脱水不净也会产生干扰。如果您的仪器没有谱图显示,那么测量结

英语口语场景对话,日常生活必备!

语口语场景对话,日常生活必备! 来自网络 一、打招呼 1. How are you doing你好吗 美国人见面时候最常用的打招呼方式就是:"Hey! How are you doing" 或是"How are you" 不然"How's going" 也很常见。我觉得这种每天跟别人打招呼的习惯,就是跟美国友人建立良好关系的开始。很多人都觉得美国人很冷漠,不跟自己打招呼,但自己又何尝不是对美国友人很冷漠呢 : 2. What's up什么事 "What's up" 也是很常用的一种打招呼方式。比方说朋友在路上看到你跟你说"Hey! " 那你通常就可以回答说"Hi! What's up" 这就是问对方近来怎样, 有什么事吗通常如果没什么事人家就会说"Not much." 不过还有一种情况也很常见,你先跟人家说"Hey! What's up" 那别人也不说"Not much",反而反问一句"What's up" 所以"What's up" 已经变成有点Hello! 的味道在里面了. "What's up" 也常被用来问人家有什么事例如有人登门拜访, 你就会说"What's up" 到底有何贵干啊总之"What's up" 在美国应用的很广,各位一定要熟记才是。 3. Could you do me a favor能不能帮我一个忙 & 人是不能独自一个人活的, 需要别人帮忙的地方总是很多, 所以就可以常讲:"Could you do me a favor" 或是"Could you give me a hand" 这算是比较正式而礼貌的讲法。有时候要请别人帮忙还不太好意思说,就可以说:Could you do me a little favor 能不能帮我一个小忙其实也许是帮大忙但也要先讲成小忙,先让对方点头才是(注意一下这里用could you 会比can you 来的客气一点)。 另外, "Can you help me" 也很常见,通常比如说我们去买东西,可是店员自己在聊天,我就会说, "Can you help me" 其实正常来说, 应该是他们主动会问"Can I help you" 或是"May I help you" 才对,但有时实在等不急了, 就直接先问了"Can you help me" 4. What are you studying你主修什么的

英语口语常用句型300句

1 Greetings I haven't seen you around lately. What are you up to 最近没看到你,忙什么呢 I just stopped by to say hello. 我只是顺道过来打个招呼。 It's fancy meeting you here. 真没想到在这儿见到你。 2 Introduction I'm afraid I didn't catch your name 我没听清你的名字。 》 I've heard a lot about you. 久仰大名。 3 Invitation Could we have the honor of your present at the party 可否请您光临我们的宴会 4 Appointment Let's make a date to go shopping this Saturday. 让我们约好这周六去逛街。 He won't be able to make your meeting this evening. 他今晚无法与您会面了。 , He'll give you a call then to make another appointment. 他会给你打电话再约时间。 5 Help Can you cover for me on Tuesday 周二能不能帮我代个班 If we can be of any help, please don’t hesitate tell us. 如果用得上我们,请不要客气。 I'm sorry to have take up so much of your time. 非常抱歉占用了你这么多时间。 He asked me to attend the meeting for him. | 他叫我代他出席会议。 6 Compliments Last night it was hard to recognize him, he was dressed to kill. 昨晚我简直就认不出是他,他打扮得超帅。 Because he finally got a date with that blond he's admired for so long.

口语常见动词总结

口语常见动词总结 在口语的英语当中, 有很多既简单又实用的动词, 几乎是每天都可以听到好几遍的. 像是prop, scoot, hit, roll 这些字眼, 各位知道它们的用法吗? 这集的笔记目的就是在帮助大家熟悉这些简单又实用的动词. 1. Don't prop your feet up. 不要把脚跷在椅子上. Prop up 是支撑的意思, 如果用手托著你的头, 这动作就叫prop your head up. 蛮实用的. 还有有的时候我们用东西把门撑住, 让它不会自动关起来, 这个就叫prop the door. 所以我住的地方楼下都会贴出告示, Don't prop the door open. 刚来美国时, 我发觉美国的女孩子作风都蛮开放的, 她们在学校时喜欢把脚跷在旁边的椅子上, 或是看电影时就把脚跷在前面的座位上, 所以在他们的观念中, prop up 其实并不算是一种坏习惯. 2. Scoot up. 向前一点. Scoot 这个字如果你去查字典, 它告诉你的解释是: "轻快地奔跑", 但是一般在日常生活中如果用到scoot 这个字的话, 则是表示稍微移动一下的意思. 比如说有一次我去图书馆念书, 我坐在我的位置上, 把走道都堵死了, 结果有一个老美要过过不去, 他要我把椅子稍微向前移动一下, 他会说Scoot up. 你也可以说sc oot up a little bit, 表示往前靠一点点. 3. Scoot over. 往旁边靠一点. Scoot up 是往前, scoot over 则是往旁边的意思. 最常见的情况就是比如照像时有人站太旁边了, 要请他靠中间一点, 就跟他说Can you scoot over? 他就会了解. 又比如说别人坐在一张长椅子上, 你要人家向旁边挪出一个位子给你, 你也可以说Scoot over please. 如果你的发音他还能了解的话,他就会往旁边靠一些, 让出一个位子给你. 4.I am going to hit the bed in ten minutes. 我在十分钟内就要上床睡觉了. 这句对于用腻了go to the bed 的人可说是一大福音, 这句话要来的更为传神, 就是指整个人倒在床上的动作, 另外还有一种说法, 但是比较少人用, 你可以说hit the hay. Hay 是稻草, 大概前人都睡稻草上, 所以才会这么说吧! 5. It won't be long before we hit the road. 离我们上路的时间不久了. Hit the road 就是上路, 所以hit 这个字用途蛮广的, 它既可以代表上床, 也可以代表上路. 这个对话是有一次我去美国的一个接待家庭住的时候, 我们正在吃早餐, 男主人就跟我说, It's not long before we hit the road. 其实他就是嫌我吃太慢了, 要我吃快一点, 因为我们快要出门了. 6. All things ought to be rolling at 4:30 所有的事情要在4:30 开始. To be rolling 就等于begin, 但是这是相当口语化的一个句子. 个人非常喜欢这句. 我忽然想到中文里也有类似的用法喔! 例如我们说, 让世界开始转动. 这个转动就相当于rolling. 有时你也可以说成Let's get the ball rolling. 让我们开始作事吧. Roll 还有一个用法跟中文的'我们可以滚了' 很像, 像有一次我跟老美去一家餐厅用完餐, 就有人说了, OK, Let's roll, let 's roll out of here. 是不是就是我们可以滚了的意思呢? 7. She is bitching at me. 她一直在对我唠叨. Bitch 一共有三种意思, 1. female dog,2. complain, 3. prostit ute. 所以, 没事不要乱用用错了! 不过一般说来, 当bitch 当动词用时就是唠叨的意思. 我的一个结了婚的同学有一次不知道是不是有感而发, 跑来跟我说, My wife bitches all the time! 8. You have to jump at the chance. 你必须把握机会. 我们说把握机会, 这个"把握"老美都是用jump 或用l eap 这两个动词, (虽然它们都是"跳"的意思) , 不知道为什么..另外opportunity 这个字也作机会讲, 所以动词也要用jump 或是leap. 例如有学校提供给你scholarship, 问你要不要去念, 你就可以说, I'll jump at the op portunity. 9. I can hold the cup for you. 我以帮你拿著这个杯子. Hold 和take 在中文都是解释成"拿", 但在英文就不一样了, hold 是拿著某样东西, 而take 是说去拿某样东西. 这句话可能很多人会讲成I can take the cup for you. 这样讲就不太对了. 10. Can you hold the door for me? 能帮我扶著门吗? 第一次老美跟我这样说, 我答Yes, 可是我却呆呆地站在那不知道他到底要我做什么. 这种情况多半是他手上拿了很多东西, 无法自己开门, 要你帮他扶著门, 不要让门关上了!

英语口语情景对话职场常用英语句型大盘点

英语口语情景对话,职场常用英语句型大盘点 外企职员必备的一项基本技能。很多员工头疼自己的英文过不了关,一碰到要用英文进行文书或是要和老外进行交流就六神无主,今天小编特地为大家搜罗了一些经典且常用的句型,大家不妨做个有心人收藏着,莫到用时方恨少呢! 1. I am writing to confirm /enquire/inform you… 我写信时要确认/询问/通知你… 2. I am writing to follow up on our earlier decision on the marketing campaign in Q2. 我写信来追踪我们之前对于第二季度营销活动的决定。 3. With reference to our telephone conversation today… 关于我们今天在电话中的谈话... 4. In my previous e-mail on October 5… 先前在10月5日所写的信… 5. As I mentioned earlier about… 如我先前所提及关于… 6. As indicated in my previous e-mail… 如我在先前的信中所提出… 7. As we discussed on the phone… 如我们上次在电话中的讨论…

8. From our decision at the previous meeting… 如我们在上次会议中的决定… 9. As you requested/per your requirement… 按照你的要求… reply to your e-mail dated April 1,we decided… 回答你在4月1日写的信,我们决定… 今天我们要讲的习惯用语都是以thin这个单词为主。Thin就是瘦,或者是很薄。要是人们有选择的话,恐怕许多人都喜欢瘦一点,而不愿意太胖。但是,今天我们要讲的前两个习惯用语都包含消极的意思。 1. wear thin 打折扣;逐渐消失 Wear在这里的意思是某一样东西在一段时间里,它的功能和价值在逐步降低,也就是中文里说的损耗。这可以指具体的东西,也可以用在其他方面。举例来说吧。 例句-1:Your patience with another person may wear thinif he keeps doing something you don't like. 要是一个人老是做你不喜欢的事,那你对他就会越来越没有耐心。 我们再来举一个例子。要是一个人问你借钱,他保证在一个月后还给你。但是,到了时候他没有还。而且还不断地找借口,拖延不还。过了半年,你对他实在没有耐心了,于是你对他说: 例句-2:Joe, remember that money you borrowed six months ago. You told me you'd pay it back in 30 days. But you keep finding reasons not to return it. Now I really need it back, and I must say that all your excuses for delay are beginning to wear thin. Joe, 记得你六个月前问我借的钱吧。当时你说你一定会在一个月后还给我。

英语口语常用句型

英语口语50句 1. According to…依照/根据……. According to the newspaper, it's a great movie. 根据报纸说,这是一部很棒的电影. 2. Am I allowed to…我可以……吗 Am I allowed to introduce our new manager Mr. Anderson to all of you 请允许我介绍我们的新经理安德森先生给大家,好吗 3. As matter of fact,…实际上……,……. As matter of fact,I don't agree with you. 实际上,我不大同意你的看法. 4.As far as I'm concerned/…就我而言,……. As far as I'm concerned, | think we should pay more attention to the safety of schoolchildren. 就我而言,我认为我们应该更关注在校儿童的安全问题. 5.As far as I know,...据我所知,……. As far as l know,he is not coming,but l may be wrong. 据我所知,他不打算来,但我或许会弄错. 6.As I just mentioned...正如我刚才提到过的,……. As I just mentioned, nobody should drop out of school unless they believe they face the opportunity of a lifetime. And even then they should reconsider. 正如我刚才提到过的,任何人都不应该辍学,除非他们相信他们面临着一生中难得的机会,尽管那样,他们还需反复思量. 7. As I see it,…在我看来,……. As I see it, he is not the right person for this position. 在我看来,他不是这个职位的合适人选. 8. As is known to us all, ... 众所周知,…… As is known to us all, Hong Kong is one of the financial centers of Asia. 众所周知,香港是亚洲金融中心之一. 9. As long as...只要…. As long as we work together, we can make the impossible possible. 只要我们一起努力,我们就能把不可能变为可能. 10.But for...若不是因为……./如果没有……. But for your generous help, we couldn't have finished the work so soon. 如果没有你的鼎力相助,我们不可能这么快完成工作的. 11.Can you believe (that)... 你相信……吗 Can you believe (that) this excellent song was composed by a high school student 你相信这首美妙的歌曲是出自一个高中生之手吗 12.Can you imagine... 你能想像……吗 Can you imagine how she lived through all these difficulties 你能想像她是怎么捱过种种困难的吗 13.Could you please explain... 你能解释一下……吗 Could you please explain why you didn't come to the meeting yesterday 你能解释一下为什么昨天没来开会吗 14.Can't we... 难道我们不能……吗

红外测油仪的原理及特点介绍

红外测油仪的原理及特点介绍 大多数物质的分子官能基能吸收红外光,利用光谱能量的吸收与转换进行内部成分的定性分析和定量计算。 红外测油仪以此为基本原理,采用红外分光光度测量,经对样品进行光谱扫描; 可显示并打印样品光谱及吸收峰的波数位置,能迅速、准确地测出水体中油份浓度的全部含量。 仪器适用于地面水、地下水、生活污水和工业废水中石油类和动植物油含量的测定。 当某特定波长的光通过被测溶液时,其光能就会被吸收。 红外测油仪检定规程工作原理: 光能被吸收的强弱与被测溶液的浓度成比例,符合比尔定律: A=log(1/T)=log(I0/I) 石油类物质浓度计算公式为: C=XA2930+YA2960+Z(A3030-A2930/F) 式中:C为油分浓度A2930、A2960、A3030为不同波长下的吸光度 X、Y、Z、F为校正系数

仪器组成: 仪器由光学系统、电气系统、微机及数据处理工作站组成。 仪器特点: 1、仪器的原理及指标完全符合水质石油类和动植物油的测定红外光度法(GB/T16488-1996)国家标准的要求。 2、可拆卸一体化光学系统,仪器体积小,重量轻,先分光后吸收,符合红外光谱特点要求,稳定性好,信噪比高。 3、采用电调制光源,即降低了光源发热强度; 以利于系统散热,同时由于无机械切光运动器件,从而简化了仪器结构,提高了仪器可靠性。 4、传感器信号处理采用锁相放大电路,提高了仪器信噪比和检出限。 5、能检验萃取剂的纯度是否符合测量需要。 6、具有谱图扫描功能,显示所使用光谱范围内吸光度曲线,从而分辨出干扰物。 7、可作为红外分光光度计使用。 8、可使用四氯乙烯等萃取剂替代四氯化碳 9、独特的比色池结构设计,适用1到5厘米任何比色皿。 10、结构简单,仪器光学系统、电气系统自成一体,集成化程度高,从而提高了仪器的可靠性和可维护性。

这50个万能句型帮你快速提升英语口语!

这50个万能句型帮你快速提升英语口语! 1.May I…? 我可以……吗? 常用句子:May I come in? 我可以进来吗? May I help you? 您需要帮忙吗? May I ask you a question? 我可以问你一个问题吗? 搭配:接动词原型。 例句:May I speak to Vincent? 请问文森在吗? May I use your telephone? 我可以借用你的电话吗? May I have a seat?

我可以坐下吗? 功能: 用这些话显得很有教养。 2. Can you …? 你能……吗? 常用句子:Can you help me? 你能帮帮我吗? Can you do me a favor? 你能帮我个忙吗? Can you please tell me where is the bus stop? 你能告诉我公共汽车站怎么走吗? 搭配:接动词原型。 例句:Can you please shut the door? 你能把门关上吗? Can you translate the sentence into Chinese for me? 你能帮我把这个句子翻译成中文吗?

Can you lend me some money? 你能借我点钱吗? 功能:用于比较熟悉的人之间,会让对方感觉亲切。如果想再客 气一点,可以把can换成could。 3. I’d like to … 我想…… 常用句子:I’d like to have a self-introduction. 我想作个自我介绍。 I’d like to talk about the matter. 我想谈谈那件事。 I’d like to have a cup of tea. 我想喝杯茶。 搭配:加动词原型。 例句:I’d like to book a double-room. 我想订一间双人房。

相关文档
相关文档 最新文档