文档库 最新最全的文档下载
当前位置:文档库 › How to Manage an Overconfident Newsvendor

How to Manage an Overconfident Newsvendor

How to Manage an Overconfident Newsvendor
How to Manage an Overconfident Newsvendor

How to Manage an Overconfident Newsvendor

David C. Croson

Cox School of Business, Southern Methodist University, Dallas, Texas 75275, dcroson@https://www.wendangku.net/doc/a810827854.html,

Rachel Croson

School of Management, University of Texas at Dallas, Richardson, Texas 75080, crosonr@https://www.wendangku.net/doc/a810827854.html,

Yufei Ren1

Department of Economics, University of Texas at Dallas, Richardson, Texas 75080, yufei.ren@https://www.wendangku.net/doc/a810827854.html,

December 2008

Abstract

Previous experimental work has shown that individuals make suboptimal decisions in newsvendor problems (e.g. Schweitzer and Cachon 2000). We present a theoretical (behavioral) model of

overconfident newsvendors that is consistent with these observed results. We show that

overconfident newsvendors place suboptimal orders (which can be either higher or lower than optimal quantities) and earn lower profits than well-calibrated newsvendors. We also derive incentive

contracts using salvage costs and price adjustments which a well-calibrated manager might offer to an overconfident newsvendor in order to induce optimal orders.

Key words: overconfidence, overprecision, newsvendor, inventory, behavioral operations

management

1We thank Xuanming Su, Elena Katok and participants in the 3rd Annual Behavioral Operations Conference, Edmonton, Alberta, July 23-25, 2008, for their invaluable comments. All mistakes are ours.

How to Manage an Overconfident Newsvendor

1. Introduction / Motivation

The newsvendor problem is a staple of Operations Management models, and serves as the basis of many models of inventory management (e.g., Sliver, Pyke and Peterson 1998; Porteus 2002). Although optimal solutions to the newsvendor problem have been known since Arrow, Harris and Marschak (1951), numerous case studie s document firms’ difficulties in implementing these solutions (e.g. Fisher and Raman 1996,Katok et al. 2001). Recently, experimental work has identified systematic deviations in ordering behavior from optimal solutions; in particular, individuals under-order in high-profit regimes and over-order in low-profit regimes (e.g., Schweitzer and Cachon 2000, Bolton and Katok 2008, Bostian et al. 2008, Benzion et al. 2007).

We propose a behavioral explanation for these observations, based on overconfidence. When individuals are overconfident, they believe their information or their estimate to be more precise (accurate) than it actually is (see Moore and Healy 2008 for a review). In the newsvendor setting, we model this overconfidence in precision as a biased belief that the distribution of demand has variance lower than its true variance. Previous research has appealed to overconfidence to explain and describe behavior in other settings (e.g. Camerer and Lovallo 1999, Odean 1998, Malmendier and Tate 2005, Hilary and Menzly 2006). We are the first to investigate the impact of overconfidence in a theoretical inventory management setting.

Given our analysis of overconfident newsvendors’ behavior, we then ask the question “H ow might a well-calibrated manager correct this bias?” We examine two types of corrective incentives. Our mo deling follows the style (although not exactly the letter) of Cachon’s (2003) coordinating contracts. In Cachon’s setting, a principal and agent have identical information and beliefs (and perfect rationality), but their differing incentives induce individual behavior inconsistent with joint profit maximization. Coordinating contracts have the potential to (at least partially) resolve these conflicting incentives, typically yielding second-best outcomes. Our setting is different, emphasizing beliefs rather than

incentives. In contrast, we assume that the manager and newsvendor have no conflicting incentives; both wish to maximize the total profits of the newsstand. They differ in their beliefs about demand, however; the manager is well-calibrated and knows the true distribution of demand, whereas the newsvendor is overconfident about the precision of his estimate of the demand distribution. We then derive incentives which the manager can offer the newsvendor in order to induce him to order the optimal inventory quantities, given the newsvendor’s biased beliefs.

We thus make two main contributions. First, we present a model of an overconfident newsvendor, and show how his orders deviate from optimal orders; the predictions of this model correspond to established experimental observation. We derive the costs of this overconfidence on profitability. Second, we derive incentives which unbiased managers can offer to overconfident newsvendors to induce optimal ordering behavior. We thus identify a technique for solving the problem of managing an overconfident agent.

The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 reviews the relevant literature. Section 3 describes our environment and defines the overconfident newsvendor. Section 4 derives the decisions made by the overconfident newsvendor and demonstrates how they differ from the classical normative solution to the newsvendor problem. Section 5 derives optimal contractual structures for an unbiased manager to offer to an overconfident newsvendor in order to induce optimal ordering. Section 6 concludes.

2. Previous literature

2.1 Overconfidence

While the theoretical operations-management literature generally addresses the actions of a fully rational agent, actual ordering decisions in practice are made by individuals. A substantial body of research from psychology (the field of Judgment and Decision Making) shows that most individuals use heuristics and suffer from a variety of biases in their decision-making. In this paper we examine the impact of one particular bias, overconfidence.

Moore and Healy (2008) present an excellent literature review of over 350 papers demonstrating overconfidence in a variety of settings over a wide range of the population. They distinguish three types of overconfidence demonstrated in the literature, each with its own implications: overestimation, overplacement, and overprecision. In the bias of overestimation, people overestimate their own abilities; they believe these abilities are greater than they indeed are. For example, students robustly overestimate their exam performance (Clayson 2005), and people overestimate the speed with which they can complete a task (Buehler, Griffin and Ross 1994). In the bias of overplacement, people believe they are better than others. For example, in Zenger (1992), 37% of professional engineers in a firm rated themselves among the top 5% of performers at the firm. Although overplacement and overestimation can (and often do) appear together, they are not necessarily causally related. As an example, individuals can simultaneously overestimate their own abilities, while believing that others are even more capable than their true abilities, and thus suffer from overestimation and underplacement simultaneously.

The third bias, which we will invoke in our model, is overprecision. In this bias, individuals believe that their estimates are more accurate than they actually are; they are overconfident about their precision. In a classic test of overprecision, participants are asked to provide estimates of varying types of information and confidence intervals around the estimates. Confidence intervals are on average unbiased (centered around an accurate mean) but too narrow; previous studies have shown that fewer than half of responses include the true answers in the offered 90% confidence intervals (e.g., Alpert and Raiffa 1982, Soll and Klayman 2004). In our model we will capture overprecision as a biased belief that a distribution (of demand) has the same mean but a lower variance than it truly has.

Previous research has appealed to overconfidence in its various forms to explain and describe a variety of behavior. Hilary and Menzly (2006) argue that analysts can become overconfident after a short series of accurate predictions, and that this causes lower accuracy in the future. Camerer and Lovallo (1999) argue that overoptimism about one’s level of ability (overestimation) can explain supraoptimal rates of market entry and entrepreneurship. Odean (1998) shows that investors who overestimate the precision of their information signals (overprecision) will trade more than is optimal and have lower

expected utilities as a result. Malmendier and Tate (2005) show that CEOs who suffer from overplacement are more likely to engage in (unprofitable) acquisitions. As far as we know, we are the first to investigate the impact of overconfidence (or overprecision) in an inventory management setting.

2.2 Newsvendor Problems

The newsvendor problem has a rich history which can be traced back to Edgeworth (1888), who first developed it as a model to study the cash holdings of banks. In the newsvendor model, an agent decides how much of a given item (for example, newspapers) to stock each day. There is a single purchasing opportunity before the start of the selling period; for example, the newsvendor has to decide how many papers he wants to purchase the night before he will sell them. The constant marginal cost of acquiring each newspaper (c) and price at which he can sell them (p) are fixed, with price higher than cost. Actual realized demand for the item is assumed to be random, drawn from a known and stationary distribution.

If the newsvendor under-stocks, he runs out of inventory and loses the expected profits from selling newspapers (p-c). If the newsvendor over-stocks, he has newspapers left over at the end of the day and can recover only their salvage value (s), assumed to be less than the marginal cost of acquiring them. He thus loses the difference (c-s) on each unit unsold.

Arrow, Harris, and Marschak (1951) calculated the famous critical fractile solution for the newsvendor problem. This optimal solution is characterized by balancing the expected cost of understocking and overstocking, and will be described in more detail below. This simple problem with its intuitively appealing optimal solution has formed the foundation for an enormous literature on stochastic inventory theory more generally. Reviews of recent theoretical work on the newsvendor model can be found in Sliver, Pyke, and Peterson (1998) and Porteus (2002).

A few previous papers have examined the impact of demand variance on the optimal newsvendor solution. For example, Naddor (1978) demonstrates that optimal orders depend only on the mean and variance of the demand distribution, and not on its specific shape. Gerchak and Mossman (1992) demonstrate that expected profits decrease when the variance of the demand distribution increases,

holding the mean constant (see also Song, 1994). Virtually all of the previous work on the newsvendor problem, however, assumes that the newsvendor fully understands the distribution from which market demand is drawn. In contrast, in our model below, the newsvendor will be mistaken about the demand distribution in a way consistent with the overprecision bias.

2.3 Empirical and Experimental Evidence

Although the optimal newsvendor solution is well-known (and, indeed, taught in virtually every MBA core operations-management course), evidence suggests that inventory managers often deviate from its recommendations. For example, Fisher and Raman (1996) model the inventory management decisions of a Skiwear firm, Sport Obermeyer. They conclude, from a sample of 339 inventory decisions, that Sport Obermeyer’s managers consistently ordered too little; had its managers ordered inventory in a way consistent with the newsvendor solution, the firm’s profits would have increased by 60%. In contrast, in another study by Katok et al. (2001), managers at Jeppesen Sanderson (a company that sells maps) systematically ordered too much. The authors derived a periodic-review inventory system which, when implemented, recommended significantly smaller orders and resulted in $800,000 of cost reduction for the firm.2

Laboratory studies run under controlled conditions help to reconcile these competing findings from the field. In the classic paper by Schweitzer and Cachon (2000), MBA students who have just learned the optimal solution for the newsvendor problem made suboptimal choices. In experimental conditions where the optimal order was higher than the mean demand (the high-profit condition), participants ordered too little (as at Sport Obermeyer). In experimental conditions where the optimal order was lower than the mean demand (the low-profit condition), participants ordered too much (as at Jeppensen Sanderson). Figure 1 from their paper shows the optimal and average orders in the two conditions.

2In a slightly different context, Olivares et al. (2008) use a newsvendor framework to explain operating-room reservations at hospitals. They similarly find suboptimal overordering behavior by doctors.

Figure 1. Results from Schweitzer and Cachon (2000) (Figure 1 from their paper)

Schweitzer and Cachon (2000) examined and rejected a number of competing explanations for

this pattern of results, including risk preferences (risk aversion or risk-seeking), Prospect Theory-based preferences (loss aversion, reflection effects, and probability weighting), waste aversion, stockout aversion, and underestimation of opportunity costs. In the end, they describe two independent and

possible biases which could explain their results: anchoring (and insufficient adjustment) and the desire to minimize ex-post inventory error (rather than ex-ante inventory error). In this paper we show analytically that a different bias -- overconfidence (in particular, overprecision) -- is consistent with their results, and thus emerges as a parsimonious unified explanation for their findings.

Four recent papers replicate the Schweitzer and Cachon (2000) result. Bolton and Katok (2008), Benzion et al. (2007) , Bostian et al. (2008) and Moritz et al. (2008) examine behavior and learning

dynamics in the newsvendor setting. All these papers find that while behavior improves over time, biased orders are still observed. Table 1 contains more detail on results from these previous experimental studies.

While Schweitzer and Cachon (2000) eliminated theories inconsistent with the observed data, only one previous paper offers a formal model of a behavioral explanation consistent these observations. Su (2008) provides a logit overlay on optimal decision-making in inventory settings. In particular, he assumes that individuals make decisions with noise; they choose the optimal order with a higher probability than suboptimal orders, but not with certainty. He demonstrates that, assuming a uniform or triangular demand distribution, this trembling-hand model of decision making generates predictions consistent with those observed in these experiments.3

Our study makes several contributions to the current literature. We are the first to propose and demonstrate that overconfidence (in fact, overprecision) is a consistent explanation for suboptimal ordering in the newsvendor problem, both in the high- and low-profit settings. Furthermore, we demonstrate the ability of overconfidence to explain these results under a general demand function. We calculate the extent of bias in the orders, and show how the order s’ deviation from optimal levels change as the level of overconfidence increases. We also calculate the cost of these deviations to the biased newsvendor. In section 5 we go one step further, asking how an unbiased manager might construct incentives to manage such an overconfident newsvendor, seeking to align their ordering decisions with those recommended by the critical fractile solution. Thus, in addition to identifying, analyzing, and assessing the impact of the problem, we also propose a possible solution.

3. Our Environment and Overconfidence

3A few contemporaneous papers take a different approach, experimentally examining the relationship between individual personality characteristics and their performance in the newsvendor problem. Moritz et al. (2008) showed that individuals who performed better on a test of cognition performed better in the newsvendor problem. Bolton et al. (2008) compared the performance of first-year undergraduates, graduate students and experienced managers, and found that all three groups behaved similarly (and suboptimally).

We follow the classical treatment of the newsvendor problem and use the following variables and assumptions about their levels, consistent with Cachon (2003):

p = unit sales price (p>0)

c = unit cost (0

s = unit salvage value (0

Q = inventory to be ordered (Q≥0)

D = quantity demanded (D≥0), a realization of a continuous random variable D

μ = mean of D

2σ = variance of D

D F = cumulative distribution function of D

()D m F μ=, the probability that actual demand is less than expected demand.

I n the newsvendor model, each morning the agent decides how many newspapers to purchase

(Q) for marginal (and constant) cost (c) per unit. He sells the newspapers over the course of the day for a constant price (p) each, where p>c. The number of papers demanded is drawn from the demand

distribution D , which is assumed to be stationary. The demand distribution D has mean μ and variance 2σ, and is described by its cumulative distribution function (D F ). When Q>D, excess newspapers are salvaged by the newsvendor with recovery s per unit, where s

β≡Pr D ≤Q =p?c p?s (1)

Since F D is continuous and strictly increasing, we can find a unique optimal solution:

*1()D Q F β-=, where F D -1 denotes the inverse CDF. We will use this benchmark of optimal orders to compare against the orders placed by an overconfident newsvendor.

For our overconfident newsvendor, his estimate of the mean consumer demand is accurate, but

his estimate of the variance of consumer demand is biased. In particular, the true market demand distribution is more variable than the market demand distribution which the newsvendor believes he faces. We adopt the general notion of “more variable ” from Ross (1983): i f 1X and 2X are nonnegative random variables and 12()()E X E X =, then 1X is said to be more variable than 2X (written X 1≥v X 2) if and only if 12[()[()]E h X E h X ≥for all convex functions h .

For practical purposes , we assume that the demand in the overconfident newsvendor’s mind o D is a mean-preserving but variance-reducing transformation of the true consumer demand D , mixing the true distribution with a zero-variance distribution around μ.4

(1),01o D D γγμγ=+-≤≤ (2)

Here γ represents the extent to which the newsvendor is well-calibrated: γ =1 corresponds to a

perfectly-calibrated newsvendor who predicts demand based on its actual distribution D , whereas γ =0 corresponds to an infinitely overconfident newsvendor who believes that Pr D =μ =1. As γ increases, overconfidence thus decreases. We will refer below to the level of overconfidence as (1- γ). Since D o is

an affine transformation of D , E [D o ]=μ and Var D o =γ2σ2, denoted 2o σfor convenience.

P ROPOSITION 3.1 (Basic Properties of D o ): D ≥v D o .

Proof : For any convex function h ,

[()][((1))][()(1)()]

[()(1)()][()](1)()[()](1)[()[()]]o E h D E h D E h D h E h D h E h D h E h D h E h D γγμγγμγγμγγμγμ=+-≤+-+-=+-=+--

The right-hand side is less than or equal to [()]E h D since Jensen’s inequality guarantees that

[()[()]]h E h D μ- is never positive. 4We use this particular formulation for two reasons. First, it accurately captures the well-documented psychological phenomenon of overprecision, dating back to Raiffa and Alpert (1982): on average individual estimates are unbiased, but confidence intervals are too small. Second, we want to isolate the impact of this particular mistake

(underestimating the variance) on ordering behavior from other possible biases. A more general formulation of newsvendor mistakes, a topic for future research, might include a misestimation of both the mean and variance of the demand distribution.

4. Overconfident Newsvendor Decisions

In this section, we study the effects of newsvendor overconfidence on the ordering decision. The results are intuitive: Because the overconfident newsvendor underestimates the variance of demand, he places orders closer to the mean of demand than the optimal order would suggest -- exactly the

empirically-observed result of Schweitzer and Cachon (2000) and subsequent papers. We show that this order bias has a linear relationship with the level of overconfidence (1-γ).

4.1 Biased Orders of Overconfident Newsvendors

We begin by deriving *o Q , the order placed by the overconfident newsvendor, and comparing it

with the optimal order *Q .

P ROPOSITION 4.1.

(a)When m β>, ()*1*.o S Q F Q μγσβ-=+<

(b)When m β<, ()*1*.o S Q F Q μγσβ-=+> (c)When m β=, **.o

Q Q μ== Proof. Appendix A provides a complete proof. The proof’s basic steps are as follows: Define X as a random variable satisfying D X σμ=+. X is thus a standardized distribution with mean 0 and variance 1. Substitute D X σμ=+ into (2) above, yielding o o D X σμ=+ Now define ()S F x as the CDF

of X and define ()S F b β=and thus 1()S F b β-=. Then *1()D

Q F b βμσ-==+and *1().o o o Q F b βμσ-==+ Since we know o σσ<, the relative order sizes depend only on the sign of b . When β>m then b >0,

and thus **o

Q Q <. When β*Q . When β=m , then b=0 and **.o Q Q μ== We note that when m β>, we are in the high-profit condition as defined by Schweitzer and

Cachon (2000) and used in subsequent experiments (op. cit.). In exactly these cases, the optimal order is higher than mean demand and overconfident newsvendors order less than is optimal – moving their order towards the demand mean. In contrast, when m β

their order towards the demand mean. Our model of overconfidence is thus consistent with the observed data in the experimental literature.

How much are these orders biased? Since 222o σγσ=, we know that **(1),o

Q Q b γσ-=- a linear relationship between the deviation from the optimal order **o

Q Q - and the level of overconfidence (1- γ). As 1-γ approaches 0, the newsvendor’s level of overconfidence (bias) goes down, and the deviation from the optimal order decreases linearly in both the high- and low-profit cases.

The effect of overconfidence also has a positive relationship with the (true) variance of demand since **()(1)o Q Q b γσ

?-=-?. When facing a market demand with higher variation, the overconfident newsvendor makes a more biased order, given the same level of overconfidence – in effect making a larger mistake.

The market ’s inherent profitability also affects the amount of deviation from optimal behavior

caused by overconfidence. More profitable markets lead to more overstocking relative to expected

demand; less profitable markets lead to more understocking relative to expected demand. As the distance b between the optimal solution Q * and the mean market demand μ increases, holding the level of overconfidence (1-γ) constant, the overconfident newsvendor’s orders move fart her away from the optimal order levels, as **()(1)0o Q Q b

γσ?-=->?. We thus expect overconfident newsvendors to make particularly large errors in both highly profitable markets (such as Sport Obermeyer) and very low-profit markets (such as Jeppson-Sanderson).

4.2 The Costs of Overconfidence

The previous section demonstrates that overconfident newsvendors order suboptimal amounts.

We have thus far focused on the newsvendor’s “mistake” in terms of quantity over - or under-ordered. How much does this mistake cost the newsvendor in terms of forgone profitability?

We can rewrite the general form for the profit of the newsvendor as:

(,)()()()()()()(,)D Q p c p c E D Q c s E Q D p c G D Q πμμ++=-------=-- (3)

where ()X + denotes max{X, 0}.

Since ()p c μ-(expected revenue from sales) is fixed, to maximize expected profit the

newsvendor simply minimizes the cost term [G(D,Q)] in (3), which (following the classic formulation of Arrow et al., 1951) includes both economic costs of overstocking and opportunity costs of understocking.

For the optimal order quantity, we can rewrite G(D,*Q )as:

*(,)()()G D Q p s E X X b σ=-≥ (4)

The overconfident newsvendor, however, will face different costs by ordering *o Q :

*(,)()()(1())()()o s G D Q c s b p s F b b p s E X X b γσγσγσγ=----+-≥ (5)

Taking the difference of the two cost functions yields

**(,)(,)(){[(1())(1())]()}b

o s s s b

G D Q G D Q p s b F b F b x f x dx γσγγ-=----+? (6) P ROPOSITION 4.2 . If *Q b μσ=+ and *o o Q b μσ=+, then **(,)(,)o

D Q D Q ππ<. Proof: Appendix B contains a complete proof that whenever m β≠:

****(,)(,)(,)(,)o o G D Q G D Q D Q D Q ππ>?<

When β=m, then ****(,)(,)(,)(,)o

o G D Q G D Q D Q D Q ππ=?=. We have thus shown that the profits of an overconfident newsvendor never exceed the profits of a well-calibrated one, and are strictly less when .m β≠ We can now turn our attention to quantifying the magnitude of these forgone profits.

P ROPOSITION 4.3. The relationship between the level of overconfidence and expected lost profit is positive and convex.

Proof. The lost profit due to overconfidence can be written as:

****(,)(,)(,)(,)o

o D Q D Q G D Q G D Q ππ-=- Taking the first and second derivatives with respect to γ yield: **((,)(,))()[()()]0(1)

o s s D Q D Q p s b F b F b ππσγγ?-=--->?- 7

2**22((,)(,))()()0(1)

o s D Q D Q p s b f b ππσγγ?-=-≥?- 8 Appendix B shows that [()()]s s b F b F b γ-is always negative, while (p-s) and σ are positive by

assumption. Thus (7), representing the first derivative of the difference in profits, is negative,

demonstrating that as (1-γ) approaches 1 (i.e., as overconfidence grows), the magnitude of lost profit increases.

The positive second derivative in (8) tells us that the loss function is not only increasing but

convex. Again, (p-s) is assumed to be positive. 2b , σ and ()s f b γare nonnegative by definition. This implies that the downward response of profits to increases in levels of overconfidence is convex: as the bias gets larger, profits fall faster. We illustrate these relationships in Figure 2, using a Gaussian demand distribution with mean 10 and variance 1 as an example. We set p=1 and s=0.4, and plot the relationship

between the level of overconfidence (1-γ) and the lost profits due to overconfidence **(,)(,)o

D Q D Q ππ-. Figure 2 shows curves for two different levels of c={0.5, 0.6} which generate two different values of β={5/6, 4/6}. Note that, since the normal distribution is symmetric about its mean, these specific cost levels will also determine the value of lost profits for the (different) costs c={0.9, 0.8} generating β ={1/6, 2/6} respectively even though the baseline profits of these four values of β are all distinct. The numerical values of these expected profits for β ={1/6, 2/6, 4/6, 5/6} are {0.85, 2.76, 3.78 , 4.85}

respectively. As shown above, these costs of overconfidence clearly increase and are convex in (1-γ) . 0

0.02

0.04

0.060.080.1

00.10.20.30.40.50.60.70.80.91β=5/6 , c=0.5 or β=1/6 , c=0.9 β=4/6, c=0.6 or β=2/6 , c=0.8

Overconfidence level: 1-γL o s t P r o f i t s

Figure 2: Profits Lost from Overconfidence when p=1, s=0.4, c ={0.5 or 0.9, 0.6 or 0.8}

5. How to Manage an Overconfident Newsvendor

We have shown that overconfident newsvendors make suboptimal inventory decisions and that

these decisions are costly. Now imagine that a well-calibrated manager of newsstands is attempting to manage an overconfident newsvendor. How might she do so?

One possibility, of course, is a hierarchical command-and-control solution; with complete

authority over the newsvendor’s actions, the manager could simply force the newsvendor to order Q*. Given that the newsvendor (and not the manager) must choose the quantity ordered, however, and that the newsvendor has both motive and method to substitute her own judgment for the manager’s, our analysis instead explores incentives or simple contractual arrangements which the manager might use to induce the newsvendor to order the optimal amount.

We are thus invoking the spirit (if not hewing to the letter) of Cachon’s (2003) method of creating coordinating contracts. In contrast, we assume there are no incentive problems between the manager and the newsvendor; both want to maximize the profits of the newsstand to the best of their abilities. We instead assume that the manager and the newsvendor have different levels of understanding of the demand distribution; the manager knows the true demand distribution, whereas the newsvendor is mistaken about it. Our challenge is thus to design an incentive structure to induce the newsvendor to order the optimal amount given his biased beliefs.5

The most straightforward way to correct the biased behavior is by changing the cost structure

facing the newsvendor, thereby inducing him to choose his order to be the same as the optimal order. The

design of this cost structure entails finding o β to solve the problem:**(,)(,)o

o o Q D Q D ββ=. Under this 5One might object that this is simply a communication problem: that the unbiased manager could simply “tell ” the overconfident newsvendor the true variance of demand. However, the overconfident newsvendor has no reason to believe that the manager’s est imate is better than his own; indeed, we can safely assume that this communication has already occurred and has already been factored into the newsvendors’ overconfident beliefs and thus into the γ-weighting from (2).

o β regime, the newsvendor who orders the optimal amount given his own beliefs will, in fact, order the correct amount given the true demand distribution.

P ROPOSITION 5.1. Define o αββ=-and *αas the value of α which induces the agent to choose

**.o Q Q = Then

111()

*()()()b

s s F s s F b

f x dx f x dx γγββα--==?? (9) Proof: if we want the agent to choose **o Q Q =, we need to set 1()s o b F βγ-=, since

**11111()()()()()o s o s s o s s o b Q Q F F F F F μγσβμσβγβββγ-----=?+=+?=?= Since *()b s b f x dx γα=?, we can find 11()

1()()()()b

s o s F s o s s o F b b f x dx f x dx F γβββββγ---=-=?=??.

From the definition of *αas the quantity adjustment required to achieve the optimal order, we can derive the following relationships from Proposition 4.:1:

If m β>, then *0α>. If m β<, then *0α<, and if m β=, *0α=.

When the optimal order is larger than the mean of the demand distribution, the manager wants the overconfident newsvendor to order more than he normally would. She thus needs to add *α to the o β he would otherwise face. The reverse holds when the optimal order is less than the mean of the demand distribution.

The manager has numerous tools available to alter the o βthat goes into the newsvendors’

decision. Here we discuss two common and easily-implemented tools frequently investigated in the operations management literature: (a) altering the salvage cost facing the newsvendor using a buyback contract (as examined in Song et al., 2008) or (b) altering the basic unit cost schedule facing the

newsvendor (as in Lariviere and Porteus, 2001).

5.1 Using Buyback Contracts

By using a buyback contract, the manager could augment the true salvage value s with a bonus

(or penalty) s I for each unit left at the end of the period. Thus the effective salvage value facing the newsvendor, which we call the return value, would be (s+s I ). Intuitively, if the overconfident

newsvendor would order less than optimal, the manager should choose a positive s I (making the return value higher than the true salvage value – a classic buyback contract), whereas if he would order more than optimal, the manager should choose a negative s I (making the return value lower than the true salvage value, e.g. demanding a fee to return, presumably coupled with monitoring to ensure that the

inventory is not surreptitiously sold to avoid the penalty). Recall that the optimal order quantity given the true salvage value is *11()()d d p c Q F F p s

β---==-. P ROPOSITION 5.2 The unique s I which induces **

o Q Q =is 2**

*()(())s

p s I p c p s αα-=-+-. Proof. When facing a return value of (s+I s ), the newsvendor will order

*11()()o o o o s

p c Q F F p s I β---==--. (10) We can rewrite *s o s s I p c p c p c p s I p s p s p s I ββα---=

=+=+------, Therefore,

***2*2***()()()(())()()(())

s s s s s

s I p c p c I p s p s I p c p s I p s p s I p s p s I p c p s αααααα-=?-=---?-+-----=-?=-+-.

We can see that the denominator is strictly positive for any value of α:

()000o p c p c p s p s ααβαβαβ--+->?>-?>-?+>?>-. Since p>c and 2()p s -is always positive, *s I has the same sign as *α.

P ROPOSITION 5.3. In the high-profit condition, *s I >0; in the low-profit condition *s I <0.When

β=m, *s I =0.

In the high-profit regime (β>m), the manager should offer to supplement the existing salvage

value by *s I to encourage the overconfident newsvendor to order more. This implies that the manager will

(probabilistically) buy back unsold goods at the end of the period at a price above the true salvage value. On the other hand, in the low-profit regime (β

buy back unsold goods below their true salvage value.

Note, however, that given an overconfidence level γ, the extra salvage value and the extra

salvage penalty are not simply negatives of each other, which would require a linear relationship between

*

s I and *

.αIn particular *2**2()()(())s I p s p c p c p s αα?--=?-+- which is not constant given that p ≠s . *s I thus does not have a linear relationship with *αand the optimal adjustments to salvage value are asymmetric.

5.2 Using Price Contracts

Instead of altering the effective salvage value facing the overconfident newsvendor, the well-

calibrated manager can subsidize (or increase) his unit cost by adding an additional cost or subsidy c I for each unit ordered. The marginal cost facing the newsvendor, which we call the apparent cost, would thus be (c+ I c ). In the high-profit regime, the overconfident newsvendor would order less than is optimal and thus the manager should choose a negative I c (making the apparent cost lower than the true marginal cost to induce larger orders). Conversely, in the low-profit regime, the overconfident newsvendor would order more than optimal and the manager should thus choose a positive I c (making the apparent cost higher than the true marginal cost). We can solve for the unique c I for a given level of overconfidence and market structure.

P ROPOSITION 5.4. The unique c I which cause **o Q Q = is **().c I p s α=--

Proof. Recall that the overconfident newsvendor’s optimal order is *1()o o o Q F β-= and that

*11()()d d p c Q F F p s

β---==- is the optimal order from the manager’s perspective . Under the additional cost (subsidy) condition, ()c c c o p c I I I p c p c p s p s p s p s p s β----=

=-=+------. Therefore, *

**()()()()b b c s c s c b b I f x dx I p s f x dx I p s p s γγαα=-=?=--?=---??. Unlike the analogous salvage value, we can see that *c I has a simple negative linear relationship

with *α. We can therefore conclude:

P ROPOSITION 5.5. In the high-profit condition,*c I <0; in the low-profit condition, *c I >0.When

β=m, *c I =0.

Thus the optimal cost adjustment for high-profit market is a subsidy (encouraging the

newsvendor to order more), while the optimal cost adjustment for low-profit markets is a surcharge (encouraging the newsvendor to order less).

5.3 Relationship between Overconfidence Level and Size of Incentive

Here we describe the relationship between the newsvendor’s level of overconfidence and the size of the incentive that the unbiased manager must offer.

P ROPOSITION 5.6. The size of the incentive is positively related to the extent of the bias.

Proof. Taking the derivative of a * (the required adjustment) with respect to the level of overconfidence yields

*2()()(1)(1)b

s b s f x dx b b f γαγγγγ??==?-?-? (11) Therefore, *(1)

αγ??-has the same sign as b . I f β>m, then *0(1)αγ?>?-. If β

0(1)αγ?

0(1)

αγ?=?-.

When the manager uses an augmented salvage value to align the newsvendor’s actions, the

derivate of s I with respect to (1-γ) yields:

*2*

*2()()(1)(1)(())(1)

s s dI I p s p c d p c p s ααγαγαγ??--?==-??--+-?- The numerator being unambiguously nonnegative, (1)

s dI d γ-will have the same sign as *.(1)αγ??-If β>m, then s I >0, *

0(1)

αγ?>?- and thus 0(1)s dI d γ>-. Similarly, when β

We can derive a similar result for adjusting marginal cost. Taking the first derivative of c I with respect to (1-γ) yields

**

*()(1)(1)(1)

c c dI I p s

d ααγαγγ???==---??-?- Sinc

e p>s, (p-s) is always positive and thus (1)

c dI

d γ- has th

e opposite sign from *(1)αγ??- and thus o

f b , given that price reductions increase quantity ordered (and vice versa for price increases). Usin

g similar reasoning, we thus find that the absolute size of the incentive (positive or negative) that the manager needs use to adjust the marginal cost is positively related to the level of overconfidence.

Figure 3a and 3b illustrate the relationship between the required subsidies (or bonuses) and the

newsvendor’s level of overconfidence using the same normal distribution and parameters as in Figure 2. In Figure 3a we show the optimal price adjustment *c I as a function of overconfidence level (1- γ). We

again depict *c I for different levels of c (ranging from 0.5 to 0.9), yielding β ranging from 1/6 to 5/6.

When β>12 (the high-profit condition) *c I is negative and decreases even further as overconfidence

勤奋就是成功之母

勤奋就是成功之母 1、人类要在竞争中生存,便要奋斗。——孙中山 2、聪明的资质、内在的干劲、勤奋的工作态度和坚韧不拔的精神。这些都是科学研究成功所需的其它条件。——贝弗里奇 3、时间是个常数,但也是个变数。勤奋的人无穷多,懒惰的人无穷少。——字严 4、聪明出于勤奋,天才在于积累。——华罗庚 5、天才是不足恃的,聪明是不可靠的,要想顺手拣来的伟大科学发明是不可想象的。——华罗庚 6、对搞科学的人来说,勤奋就是成功之母!——茅以升 7、勤奋就是成功之母。——茅以升 8、努力学习,勤奋工作,让青春更加光彩。——王光美 9、不闻不若闻之,闻之不若见之,见之不若知之,知之不若行之,学至于行而止矣。——荀况 10、世上无难事,只要肯攀登。——毛泽东 11、形成天才的决定因素应该是勤奋。…有几分勤学苦练是成正比例的。——郭沫若 12、什么是天才!我想,天才就是勤奋的结果。——郭沫若

13、天才这个字本来含意极其暖昧,它的定义,决不是所谓“生而知之,不学而能” 的。天地间生而知之的人没有。不学而能的人也没有。天才多半由于努力养成。天才多半由于细心养成。——郭沫若 14、哪里有天才,我是把别人喝咖啡的功夫,都用在工作上的。——鲁迅 15、在学习上做一眼勤、手勤、脑勤,就可以成为有学问的人。——吴晗 16、在天才和勤奋两者之间,我毫不迟疑地选择勤奋,她是几乎世界上一切成就的催产婆。——爱因斯坦 17、精神的浩瀚、想象的活跃、心灵的勤奋:就是天才。——狄德罗 18、“天才就是勤奋”,曾经有人这样说过。如果这话不完全正确,那至少在很大程度上是正确的。——李卜克内西 19、所谓天才人物指的就是具有毅力的人、勤奋的人、入迷的人和忘我的人。——萧伯纳 20、业精于勤,荒于嬉;行成于思,毁于随。——韩愈 21、天才就是无止境刻苦勤奋的能力。——卡莱尔 22、发明是百分之一的聪明加百分之九十九的勤奋。——爱迪生

设计概论思考题

思考题 1.设计学怎样作为一门独立学科分离出来的? 作为一门新兴的学科,设计学的产生是20世纪以来的事件;作为一门专门的学科,它毫无疑问有着它自己的研究对象。由于设计与特定的物质生产与科学技术的关系,这使得设计学本身具有自然科学的客观性特征;而设计与特定社会的政治、文化、艺术之间所存在的显而易见的关系作为一门新兴的学科,设计学的产生是20世纪以来的事件;作为一门专门的学科,它毫无疑问有着它自己的研究对象。由于设计与特定的物质生产与科学技术的关系,这使得设计学本身具有自然科学的客观性特征;而设计与特定社会的政治、文化、艺术之间所存在的显而易见的关系,又使得设计学在另一方面有着特殊的意识形态色彩。,又使得设计学在另一方面有着特殊的意识形态色彩。 2.设计史,设计理论与涉及批评对于设计实践分别具有怎样的意义? 我们一般将设计学划分为设计史、设计理论和设计批评三个分支。设计史必须要研究科技史与美术史,研究设计理论必然要研究相关的工程学、材料学和心理学,研究设计批评必然要研究美学、民俗学和伦理学的理论要求。 3如何看待中国古代设计思想对现代设计的意义? 4从历史与社会角度论述设计与艺术的关系? 5设计与科学之间是如何相互影响相互促进的?(改) 由于科学技术在社会生产及其他领域中的广泛应用,人类在自然界面前获得空前的主动地位,人类的生产、经济、军事等实践活动对自然生态环境产生着越来越巨大而深远的影响。生命科学、遗传学的发展,在不断地揭示生物遗传和变异规律的基础上为人类创造着新的生产力,给人类带来了显著的经济和社会效益。现代科学技术和人类生活紧密地结合在—起,社会的科学化技术化速度不断加快,规模也不断扩大。 工业和科学技术以渐进的甚至惊人的突变速度发展,传统的手工艺设计和艺术美学理念被工业社会和技术变革所打破,设计不得不接受工业和技术的洗礼。 进行现代运动的设计师想通过大规模的生产最终得出反对装饰风格的纯几何形式。最鲜明的代表就是包豪斯设计学校。他们致力于从事最新观念和最先进的设计,他们强调一种单一的现代运动的设计方法,即利用现代材料和工业生产技术,以原色红、蓝、黄和圆形以及方形为基础形成纯几何形式。在后来的发展中,现代设计也被称为国际风格。这是因为这一新方向产生的巨大影响而予以的美称。在现代设计运动中有一部分人是服从现代设计的规则的。而在同时期还有部分人并不愿意完全的服从这一当前比较流行的规则。服从规则的突出的代表有荷兰的风格派,俄罗斯构成派,斯堪的那维亚的阿尔多和阿斯普朗德的设计,还有美国的流线型设计。尽管这些设计和制作展示出了复杂和多变性,但是他们其中始终有着共同的联系。例如,荷兰艺术和设计运动中的风格派,提倡严格的审美观,在创作中使用原色,平面和立体的造型都严格按照几何的式样。此次运动中法国和意大利也有杰出的代表。意大利未来派把自己和左翼法西斯意识形态联系在一起,要利用工业文化建立一个全新的现代国家。法国勒.柯布西埃的建筑设计艺术也是把纯粹的现代主义精神具体化的杰出代

化工原理》实验思考题题目及答案

实验一流体流动阻力测定 1、倒∪型压差计的平衡旋塞和排气旋塞起什么作用怎样使用 平衡旋塞是打开后,可以进水检查是否有气泡存在,而且能控制液体在U型管中的流量而排气旋塞,主要用于液柱调零的时候使用的,使管内形成气-水柱 操作方法如下: 在流量为零条件下,打开光滑管测压进水阀和回水阀,旋开倒置U型管底部中间的两个进水阀,检查导压管内是否有气泡存在。若倒置U型管内液柱高度差不为零,则表明导压管内存在气泡,需要进行赶气泡操作。 开大流量,使倒置U型管内液体充分流动,以赶出管路内的气泡;若认为气泡已赶净,将流量阀关闭;慢慢旋开倒置U型管上部的放空阀,打开底部左右两端的放水阀,使液柱降至零点上下时马上关闭,管内形成气-水柱,此时管内液柱高度差应为零。然后关闭上部两个放空阀。 2、如何检验测试系统内的空气已经排除干净 在流量为零条件下,打开光滑管测压进水阀和回水阀,旋开倒置U型管底部中间的两个进水阀。若倒置U型管内液柱高度差不为零,则表明导压管内存在气泡,需要进行赶气泡操作。知道,U型管高度差为零时,表示气泡已经排干净。 3、U型压差计的零位应如何调节 操作方法如下: 在流量为零条件下,打开光滑管测压进水阀和回水阀,旋开倒置U型管底部中间的两

个进水阀,检查导压管内是否有气泡存在。若倒置U型管内液柱高度差不为零,则表明导压管内存在气泡,需要进行赶气泡操作。 开大流量,使倒置U型管内液体充分流动,以赶出管路内的气泡;若认为气泡已赶净,将流量阀关闭;慢慢旋开倒置U型管上部的放空阀,打开底部左右两端的放水阀,使液柱降至零点上下时马上关闭,管内形成气-水柱,此时管内液柱高度差应为零。然后关闭上部两个放空阀。 4、测压孔的大小和位置、测压导管的粗细和长短对实验有无影响为什么 有,有影响。跟据公式 hf=Wf/g=λlu平方/2d也就是范宁公式,是沿程损失的计算公式。因此,根据公式,测压孔的长度,还有直径,都是影响测压的因素。再根据伯努利方程 测压孔的位置,大小都会对实验有影响。 5、在测量前为什么要将设备中的空气排净怎样能迅速地排净 因为如果设备含有气泡的话,就会影响U型管的读数,读数不准确,便会影响实验结果的准确性。要迅速排净气体,首先要开大流量,使倒置U型管内液体充分流动,以赶出管路内的气泡;若认为气泡已赶净,将流量阀关闭。 6、在不同设备(包括相对粗糙度相同而管径不同)、不同温度下测定的λ-Re数据能否关联在同一条曲线上 答,不能,因为,跟住四个特征数,分别是长径比l/d,雷诺数Re,相对粗糙度 E/d,还有欧拉数Eu=wf/u的平方。即使相对粗糙度相同的管,管径和温度不同都会影响雷诺数及摩

成功是成功之母的例子

成功是成功之母的例子 人们常说,成功孕育于失败之中。此话当然不假。然而,是否曾想到过成功也是成功之母呢?以下是为大家整理的关于成功是成功之母的例子,欢迎阅读! 成功是成功之母的例子1: “成功是成功之母,失败是失败之母”可信吗? 2007年11月《南方人物周刊》记者采访中国80后作家韩寒:“你怎么看待成功?” 韩寒:“成功这个东西,很难说,我今天心情好,我会觉得我成功了,如果心情不好,我就觉得不算成功。” 记者:“比如说一个男人到了30岁,说我没有车,没房……” 韩寒:“那肯定不够成功。……成功是成功之母,失败是失败之母。就像我们赛车一样,如果你在一个拐弯出了问题,以后你每次到这个拐弯的时候,你都会心虚。如果你一直成功,一直成功,你就会一直特别有信心。很多事情都是这样的。” 韩寒面对记者的提问,从个人感觉和心情好坏出发,仿照“失败是成功之母”成语,提出“成功是成功之母,失败是失败之母。”,认为“很多事情”成功就一直成功,失败就永远失败。这种说法可信吗? 如何看待成功与失败,正确对待两者之间关系,这是青年朋友历

来关注的一个问题,也是一个人的人生态度问题。古人早就说过:“失败者成功之母。”这是一条约定俗成的成语,是人民群众从改造世界和认识世界的长期实践中总结出来的经验。它告诫我们无论做什么事情,都要从失败中找出差距,吸取教训,就能变失败为成功。 历史上许多名人成就大事业,往往都经历过失败的挫折的。春秋末期孔子57岁周游列国,遭到无数次的冷落和打击,没有一个君主采用他的治国学说。他潜心治学,整理《诗》《书》《春秋》等西周文献,办私学培养“三千弟子,七十二贤人”,成为世界最伟大的教育家,儒家学说的创始人。西汉时期司马迁因为李陵事件遭受腐刑,他忍受难以启齿的屈辱,以顽强的毅力发愤著文,完成了史学巨著《史记》,彪炳千秋,光照万代,开创了我国纪传体通史的先河。这不都验证了“失败是成功之母”的道理吗? 我们在人生征途上遇到的不都是鲜花、阳光和彩虹,有时也有毒草、阴云和风雨,正如一首歌唱道:“不经历风雨,哪能见彩虹?”人生的历史不是直线的,而是波浪式的不能只要成功,回避失败,不能只喜欢顺境,拒绝逆境。我们要客观地看待成功与失败,不能以个人感觉和心情来评断,韩寒说“我今天心情好,我会觉得我成功了,如果心情不好,我就觉得不算成功。”这句话至少是本末倒置了,我认为心情好与不好,决定不了能否成功与失败,而恰恰相反,你的成功与失败才能带来心情的好与不好。试想,哪一个成功者不为事业上的成就而喜笑颜开、心花怒放呢? 我们顺着韩寒的感觉走,理解他的“成功是成功之母,失败是失

关于成功的三大定律

成功三大定律 关于成功,有很多定律,比较有名的就是荷花定律、竹子定律和金蝉定律。 无论是荷花定律、竹子定律,还是金蝉定律,他们都有共同的意义: 成功,需要厚积薄发, 要忍受煎熬,要耐得住寂寞, 坚持,坚持,再坚持, 直到最后成功的那一刻。 荷花定律 一个池塘里的荷花,每一天都会以前一天的2倍数量在开放。 如果到第30天,荷花就开满了整个池塘。 请问:在第几天池塘中的荷花开了一半?第15天?错!是第29天。这就是荷花定律。 第一天开放的只是一小部分,第二天,它们会以前一天的两倍速度开放。 到第29天时荷花仅仅开满了一半,直到最后一天才会开满另一半。 也就是说:最后一天的速度最快,等于前29天的总和。 这就是著名的荷花定律。

这其中藏着深刻的道理就是:成功需要厚积薄发,需要积累沉淀。 这个定律最早是听过马云的一个公开演讲,而透过这个定律去联想人生,你会发生,很多人的一生就像池塘里的荷花,一开始用力地开,玩命地开......。 但渐渐的,人们开始感到枯燥甚至是厌烦,你可能在第9天、第19天甚至第29天的时候放弃了坚持。 这时,这个时候的放弃,往往离成功只有一步之遥。 很多时候,甚至可以说大多时候,人能获得成功,关键在于毅力。 据说人这一生大概能遇到7次左右的机会,都是可以改变人生的机会,而这样的机会往往都是在前期日复一日的投入和坚持才能遇到这样的机会。 所以说,如果有梦想就要先动起来,然后坚定不移的去执行下去。竹子定律 竹子用了4年的时间,仅仅长了3cm。 从第五年开始,以每天30cm的速度疯狂地生长,仅仅用了六周的时间,就长到了15米。 其实,在前面的四年,竹子将根在土壤里延伸了数百平米。 做人做事亦是如此。 不要担心你此时此刻的付出得不到回报,因为这些付出都是为了扎根。 人生需要储备,有多少人,没能熬过那三厘米?

艺术设计概论总结含课后答案

艺术设计概论 第一章导论 设计是文化和文明的产物,又创造着新文化和新文明。 第一节、艺术设计的概念与定义 一、“设计”的概念 1974《大不列颠百科全书》“Design: blah blah........只要是为了一定目的而从事设想、规划、计划、安排、布置、筹划、策划的都可以说是‘设计’” 郝伯特·西蒙:“凡是以现存情形改变成想望情形,为目标而构想行动方案的人都在搞设计。”——最本质的意义是计划/设计,即预设一定的目标并为此而建立方案。(不是以大工业生产为前提的意义) 二、设计的意义 设计是人类改变原有事物,使其变化、增益、更新、发展的创造性活动。设计是构想和解决问题的过程,它涉及人类一切有价值的创造活动。【设计的宏观定义】“一种对目标问题的求解活动” “从现存事实转向未来可能的思想跃迁” “......”“......” 1950麦德华·考夫曼·琼尼:现代设计的12项定义:【大工业生产后的定义】 1)应满足现代设计的需要

2)应体现时代精神 3)应从不断发展的纯美术与纯科学中不断汲取营养(自我发展) 4)应灵活运用新材料、新技术,并不断使其发展(与时俱进) 5)通过运用适当的材料和技术手段,不断丰富产品的造型、肌理、色彩等效果(外观创新) 6)应明确的表达对象的意图、绝不能模棱两可(理念清晰) 7)应体现使用材料所具备的区别于他种材料的特性及美感(忠于材料) 8)应明确表达产品的制作方法,不能使用表面可行、实际不能适应大量生产的欺骗手段(诚实) 9)在实用、材料、工艺的表现手法上,应给人以视觉的满足,特别应强调整体效果的满足(效果展示) 10)应给人单纯洁净的美感,避免繁琐的处理 11)必须熟悉和掌握机械设备的功能 12)追求豪华情调的同时,必须顾及消费者节制的欲求及价格问题(物美价廉) 1957国际工业设计学会联合会(ICSID)1964年定义:“工业设计是一种创造性活动,他的目的是解决工业产品的造型质量,这些造型质量不但是外部特征,而且主要是结构和功能的关系,他从生产者和使用者的观点把一个系统转变为连贯的统一。工业设计扩大到包括人类环境的一切方面,仅售工业生产可能性的限制。”【设计从物向人的转变】【表明了设计的创造性质和意义;注重内部结构、功能与外观形态的统一;从人的需要出发(即

成功三大定律

荷花定律 一个池塘里的荷花,每一天都会以前一天的2倍数量在开放。如果到第30天,荷花就开满了整个池塘。请问:在第几天池塘中的荷花开了一半?第15天?错!是第29天。这就是荷花定律。 第一天开放的只是一小部分,第二天,它们会以前一天的两倍速度开放。到第29天时荷花仅仅开满了一半,直到最后一天才会开满另一半。 也就是说:最后一天的速度最快,等于前29天的总和。 这就是著名的荷花定律。 很多时候,甚至可以说大多时候,人能获得成功,关键在于毅力。 据说人这一生大概能遇到7次左右的机会,都是可以改变人生的机会,而这样的机会往往都是在前期日复一日的投入和坚持中才能遇到这样的机会。 竹子定律 竹子用了4年的时间,仅仅长了3cm。从第五年开始,以每天30cm的速度疯狂地生长,仅仅用了六周的时间,就长到了15米。其实,在前面的四年,竹子将根在土壤里延伸了数百平米。做人做事亦是如此。不要担心你此时此刻的付出得不到回报,因为这些付出都是为了扎根。国学大师钱穆说:“古往今来有大成就者,诀窍无他,都是能人肯下笨劲。” 胡适也说:这个世界聪明人太多,肯下笨功夫的人太少,所以成功者只是少数人。这就叫竹子定律。 金蝉定律 蝉,要先在地下暗无天日地生活三年(有一种美国的蝉,要在地下生活17年),忍受各种寂寞和孤独,依靠树根的汁一点点长大。在夏天的一个晚上,悄悄爬到树枝上,一夜之间蜕变成知了。然后期待太阳升起的那一刻,它就可以飞向天空,冲向自由。这就叫金蝉定律。 很多人的一生就像池塘里的荷花,一开始用力盛开,但是总感觉自己绽放的不够,所以渐渐感到厌倦,在第10天、第20天、甚至第29天的时候,选择了放弃。越接近成功越困难,越需要坚持。马云曾说:“今天很残酷,明天更残酷,后天很美好,但是大多数人死在明天晚上,看不到后天的太阳。”大部分人都是

设计概论试题与答案一

设计概论试题与答案第一套 注意:(红色字体为重点) 第一章设计的内涵 思考题答题要点 1."设计"(Design)的本义是什么? 设计(Design)源于拉丁文Designave,其本义是"徽章、记号",即事物或人物得以被认识的依据或媒介,在中国,设计最初是分开使用的,"设"指预想、策划,"计"指特定的方法策略等。 2.不同的学者对设计的理解提出了哪些较有代表性的观点? 设计是人类的行为; 设计的本质是人为事物; 设计是人类生活方式的设计。 3.如何理解设计的内涵? 我们可以从广义和狭义两个方面来理解设计的内涵: 从广义的角度来理解,design最基本的意义是计划乃至设计,即心怀一定的目的,并以其实现为目标而建立的方案,这个界定几乎涵盖了人类有史以来的一切文明创造活动,其所蕴含着的构思和创造性行为过程,则是现代设计的内涵和灵魂; 从狭义的角度来理解,design特指在一般的计划和设计中,对构成艺术作品的各种构成要素,在各部分之间或者部分与整体的结构关系上,

组织成为一个作品的创意过程。 4.如何理解艺术与设计的关系? ①对"艺术"《辞海》解释为:"人类以情感和想象为特性珠把握和反映世界的一种特殊方式。即通过审美创造活动再现现实和表现情感理想,在想象中实现审美主体和审美客体的互相对象化。具体说,它是人们现实生活和精神世界的形象反映,也是艺术家知识、情感、理想、意念综合心理活动的有机产物。" ②设计虽然超越了纯艺术,存在于设计、生产或制作的全过程,和技术、材料、工艺、市场、消费、等因素紧密地结合在一起,但它与艺术创作并不能截然分开,设计师的设计至始至终总是要考虑到具体设计对象,根据生产技术条件和制作技艺的可行性,而进行创造性工作,这个创造性过程始终与审美发生联系。 5.什么是设计的形式?它包括哪些因素? 设计的形式指形态、色彩、肌理等外在造型形式,形式是为内容服务的,形式受到实用功能的制约,同时又对认知功能和审美功能的形成具有重要的作用。 ①形态:通常指某种特定的外形,即物体在空间中的特定形态。物体的形态特征是我们区别不同物体的依据,这里的形态概念既指设计物外形,也包括设计物内在结构,是设计物的内外要素的统一的综合体,构成形态的基本形式有点、线、面、体等; 设计物的形态创造要善于运用变化与统一,韵律与节奏,主从与响应、过渡与均衡、对比与协调、比例与尺度、比拟与联想等多种造型手法,以达

水力学实验报告思考题答案(供参考)

水力学实验报告 实验一流体静力学实验 实验二不可压缩流体恒定流能量方程(伯诺利方程)实验 实验三不可压缩流体恒定流动量定律实验 实验四毕托管测速实验 实验五雷诺实验 实验六文丘里流量计实验 实验七沿程水头损失实验 实验八局部阻力实验 实验一流体静力学实验 实验原理 在重力作用下不可压缩流体静力学基本方程 或 (1.1) 式中:z被测点在基准面的相对位置高度; p被测点的静水压强,用相对压强表示,以下同; p0水箱中液面的表面压强; γ液体容重; h被测点的液体深度。 另对装有水油(图1.2及图1.3)U型测管,应用等压面可得油的比重S0有下列关系: (1.2) 据此可用仪器(不用另外尺)直接测得S0。 实验分析与讨论

1.同一静止液体内的测管水头线是根什么线? 测压管水头指,即静水力学实验仪显示的测管液面至基准面的垂直高度。测压管水头线指测压管液面的连线。实验直接观察可知,同一静止液面的测压管水头线是一根水平线。 2.当P B<0时,试根据记录数据,确定水箱内的真空区域。 ,相应容器的真空区域包括以下三部分: (1)过测压管2液面作一水平面,由等压面原理知,相对测压管2及水箱内的水体而言,该水平面为等压面,均为大气压强,故该平面以上由密封的水、气所占的空间区域,均为真空区域。 (2)同理,过箱顶小水杯的液面作一水平面,测压管4中,该平面以上的水体亦为真空区域。 (3)在测压管5中,自水面向下深度某一段水柱亦为真空区。这段高度与测压管2液面低于水箱液面的高度相等,亦与测压管4液面高于小水杯液面高度相等。 3.若再备一根直尺,试采用另外最简便的方法测定γ0。 最简单的方法,是用直尺分别测量水箱内通大气情况下,管5油水界面至水面和油水界面至油面的垂直高度h和h0,由式,从而求得γ0。 4.如测压管太细,对测压管液面的读数将有何影响? 设被测液体为水,测压管太细,测压管液面因毛细现象而升高,造成测量误差,毛细高度由下式计算 式中,为表面张力系数;为液体的容量;d为测压管的内径;h为毛细升高。常温(t=20℃)的水,=7.28dyn/mm,=0.98dyn/mm。水与玻璃的浸润角很小,可认为cosθ=1.0。于是有 (h、d单位为mm)

一个人想要成就大事,须知三大定律

一个人想要成就大事,须知三大定律 所谓定律也就是规律,是证明了的有效的规律,你想要成功就需要遵循这些规律,否则你会走偏,无法到达成功的目的地。 一个人想要成功,并不是多说人所说的,你要努力,你要勤奋,你要有诚信,你就可以获得成功。一个残酷的事实是,那些真正成功的人,往往从来不会把自己的经验和成功秘诀告诉你,因为他害怕你也会和他一样成功,从而和他形成竞争。 所以,你所能够接触到的,那些告诉你如何成功的方法,或多或少都是别人精心“编织”的谎言,目的就是误导你,不让你成功。这就好比你问一个干生意的人,他从来不会告诉你自己挣钱很容易,挣的钱比打工的人多好几倍,他只会想你诉苦,告诉你挣钱多不容易。 一个人想要成就大事,须知三大定律,不然难有作为 那么到底怎么样才能够成功呢?或者说想要成功,我们该怎么做呢?以下三大定律可以帮助你掌握真正成功的方法,你需要时刻遵守。 01 什么热门做什么 想要有所成就,就需要看目前哪个领域是热门,然后就做这个领域,因为这个领域热门,所以必然会催生巨大的机会,拥有巨大的市场,你只要做,那么就可能会赚到大钱。而如果这个领域已经开始走下坡路了,你才进入去做,那么你就很难挣到钱。就比如,当初电脑刚开始普及的时候,是非常热门的一个领域,如果你销售电脑,那么你就能够挣到很多钱,后来电脑不行了,智能手机开始普及,你去销售智能手机,就能够挣到很多钱。 一个人想要成就大事,须知三大定律,不然难有作为 02 不要追求长久追求阶段 很多人干什么都想着做百年老店,觉得干什么都需要长久才行。就像很多人说,公司里面老板不能够识别人才,这公司肯定干不长久。这种思维都是错误的,因为可能人家压根就没想着长久干下去,就是阶段性的赚钱,这个领域不行了,就直接换其他领域。时代变化太迅速了,三五年之后形势就变了,追求长久只会让你被时代所淘汰。所以,干什么事情,不要想的太远,最多规划2~3年,现阶段做现阶段的事情。就像上面说的,一开始卖电脑很挣钱,但是后来干的人多了,普及多了,电脑需求也就下去了,也就不挣钱了,这个阶段就需要换项目卖手机了,等到手机不行了,然后再变其他项目。 一个人想要成就大事,须知三大定律,不然难有作为 03

失败乃成功之母

失败乃成功之母 失败是挫折,是痛苦,但它又可以转成为成功。 认识总是从实践开始的,总是从感性认识到理性认识。正如牛顿所说:“如果你问一个善于溜冰的人怎么样获得成功时,他会告诉你:‘跌到了,爬起来!这就是成功。’”有谁见过没跌到过议席就成为溜冰能手的呢?“那些自信而不介意于暂时失败的人!”这是世间的普遍真理。 肯德基的创始人是山德士上校,山德士上校是位退伍的军人,退伍后他身无分文,每个月的生活只能靠政府发的补贴金来维持。山德士有一个炸鸡的秘方,他决定向各大食品公司推荐他的秘方,但每家公司面对这一个衣衫褴褛的人都拒绝了。经过1001次的努力,他终于被一家食品公司认可。在而后短短的一年半之内,他开了三百家连锁店,受到人们的喜欢。是什么使他成功的呢?是一次次失败后他都不放弃。为什么他不放弃呢?因为他坚信失败是成功之母。 爱迪生发明电灯时,为了寻找合适作灯丝的材料,他和助手反复试验了一千多种材料,但都以失败而告终。他的助手十分灰心丧气,想放弃这个项目了,便对爱迪生说:“先生,我们已经失败了一千多次了。看来没希望了。”可爱迪生却笑了:“不,我认为这不是失败,相反,我们已经成功找到了一千多种不适宜作灯丝的材料。即使我们没有发明电灯,后人也可以从我们的探索中受到启发,少走以千次弯路,而最终发明电灯。”后来,经过爱迪生和助手们的一年努力,他们终

于发明了电灯。 唐朝著名学者陆羽,从小是个孤儿,被智积禅师抚养长大。陆羽虽身在庙中,却不愿终日诵经念佛,而是喜欢吟读诗书。陆羽执意下山求学,遭到了禅师的反对。禅师为了给陆羽出难题,同时也是为了更好地教育他,便叫他学习冲茶。在钻研茶艺的过程中,陆羽碰到了一位好心的老婆婆,不仅学会了复杂的冲茶的技巧,更学会了不少读书和做人的道理。当陆羽最终将一杯热气腾腾的苦丁茶端到禅师面前时,禅师终于答应了他下山读书的要求。后来,陆羽撰写了广为流传的《茶经》,把祖国的茶艺文化发扬光大! “失败乃成功之母”不仅应当成为我们喜爱的一句格言,更重要的是要成为我们行动的指南。“宝剑锋从磨砺出,梅花香自苦寒来”,从失败中获益,从勤奋中崛起,这就是有志青年的成才道路。 六年级一班 王玉

作文成功三大定律

作文成功三大定律: 荷花定律 一个池塘里的荷花,每一天都会以前一天的2倍数量在开放。如果到第30天,荷花就开满了整个池塘。请问:在第几天池塘中的荷花开了一半?第15天?错!是第29天。这就是荷花定律。 第一天开放的只是一小部分,第二天,它们会以前一天的两倍速度开放。到第29天时荷花仅仅开满了一半,直到最后一天才会开满另一半。也就是说:最后一天的速度最快,等于前29天的总和。这就是著名的荷花定律。 这其中藏着深刻的道理就是:成功需要厚积薄发,需要积累沉淀。这个定律最早是听过马云的一个公开演讲,而透过这个定律去联想人生,你会发生,很多人的一生就像池塘里的荷花,一开始用力地开,玩命地开......。 但渐渐的,人们开始感到枯燥甚至是厌烦,你可能在第9天、第19天甚至第29天的时候放弃了坚持。 这时,这个时候的放弃,往往离成功只有一步之遥。很多时候,甚至可以说大多时候,人能获得成功,关键在于毅力。 据说人这一生大概能遇到7次左右的机会,都是可以改变人生的机会,而这样的机会往往都是在前期日复一日的投入和坚持才能遇到这样的机会。所以说,如果有梦想就要先动起来,然后坚定不移的去执行下去。

贰 竹子定律 竹子用了4年的时间,仅仅长了3cm。从第五年开始,以每天30cm的速度疯狂地生长,仅仅用了六周的时间,就长到了15米。其实,在前面的四年,竹子将根在土壤里延伸了数百平米。 做人做事亦是如此。不要担心你此时此刻的付出得不到回报,因为这些付出都是为了扎根。人生需要储备,有多少人,没能熬过那三厘米? 什么叫价值?同是两根竹子,一支做成了笛子,一支做成了晾衣杠。晾衣杠不服气的问笛子:我们都是同一片山上的竹子,凭什么我天天日晒雨淋,不值一文。而你却价值千金呢?笛子回答说:因为你只挨了一刀,而我却经历了千刀万剐,精雕细做,晾衣杠此时沉默了。 人生亦是如此,经得起打磨,耐得起寂寞,扛得起责任,肩负起使命,人生才会有价值。看见别人辉煌的时候,不要嫉妒,因为别人付出的比你多。 国学大师钱穆说:“古往今来有大成就者,诀窍无他,都是能人肯下笨劲。”胡适也说:“这个世界聪明人太多,肯下笨功夫的人太少,所以成功者只是少数人。”

设计概论思考题答题要点资料

第一章思考题答题要点 1."设计"(Design)的本义是什么? 设计(Design)源于拉丁文Designave,其本义是"徽章、记号",即事物或人物得以被认识的依据或媒介,在中国,设计最初是分开使用的,"设"指预想、策划,"计"指特定的方法策略等。2.不同的学者对设计的理解提出了哪些较有代表性的观点? 设计是人类的行为; 设计的本质是人为事物; 设计是人类生活方式的设计。 3.如何理解设计的内涵? 我们可以从广义和狭义两个方面来理解设计的内涵: 从广义的角度来理解,design最基本的意义是计划乃至设计,即心怀一定的目的,并以其实现为目标而建立的方案,这个界定几乎涵盖了人类有史以来的一切文明创造活动,其所蕴含着的构思和创造性行为过程,则是现代设计的内涵和灵魂; 从狭义的角度来理解,design特指在一般的计划和设计中,对构成艺术作品的各种构成要素,在各部分之间或者部分与整体的结构关系上,组织成为一个作品的创意过程。 4.如何理解艺术与设计的关系? ①对"艺术"《辞海》解释为:"人类以情感和想象为特性珠把握和反映世界的一种特殊方式。即通过审美创造活动再现现实和表现情感理想,在想象中实现审美主体和审美客体的互相对象化。具体说,它是人们现实生活和精神世界的形象反映,也是艺术家知识、情感、理想、意念综合心理活动的有机产物。" ②设计虽然超越了纯艺术,存在于设计、生产或制作的全过程,和技术、材料、工艺、市场、消费、等因素紧密地结合在一起,但它与艺术创作并不能截然分开,设计师的设计至始至终总是要考虑到具体设计对象,根据生产技术条件和制作技艺的可行性,而进行创造性工作,这个创造性过程始终与审美发生联系。 5.什么是设计的形式?它包括哪些因素? 设计的形式指形态、色彩、肌理等外在造型形式,形式是为内容服务的,形式受到实用功能的制约,同时又对认知功能和审美功能的形成具有重要的作用。 ①形态:通常指某种特定的外形,即物体在空间中的特定形态。物体的形态特征是我们区别不同物体的依据,这里的形态概念既指设计物外形,也包括设计物内在结构,是设计物的内外要素的统一的综合体,构成形态的基本形式有点、线、面、体等; 设计物的形态创造要善于运用变化与统一,韵律与节奏,主从与响应、过渡与均衡、对比与协调、比例与尺度、比拟与联想等多种造型手法,以达到传达视觉信息的目的。 ②色彩:即颜色,物体在有选择地吸收、反射、透射色光的时候,由于物体的物理性质不同而呈现出不同的色彩。 ③肌理:肌理是表达人对设计物表面纹理特征的感受。一般认为,肌理与质感是同义词,对设计的形式因素来说,当肌理与质感相联系时,它一方面是作为材料的表现形式而被人们所感受,另一方面则体现在通过先进的工艺手法,创造新的肌理形态,不同的材质,不同的工艺手法可以产生各种不同的肌理效果,并能创造出丰富的外在造型形式。 6.如何理解设计的功能? 《辞海》中对"功能"是这样解释的:"一为事功和能力,二为功效、作用"。设计的功能主要体现在四个方面:

流体力学实验思考题解答全

流体力学课程实验思考题解答 (一)流体静力学实验 1、 同一静止液体内的测压管水头线就是根什么线? 答:测压管水头指γp Z +,即静水力学实验仪显示的测压管液面至基准面的垂直高度。测压 管水头线指测压管液面的连线。从表1、1的实测数据或实验直接观察可知,同一静止液面的测压管水头线就是一根水平线。 2、 当0

失败是成功之母的经典例子7个

失败是成功之母的经典例子7个 篇一:七年级历史上课本习题答案(内容全) 七年级历史书习题答案 1、山顶洞人的头部与北京人头部哪些地方不一样? 山顶洞人头部的前额、眉骨和嘴巴都摆脱了猿类的特点,模样同现代人基本上一样。 2、想一想,北京人是怎样得到火的? 大自然雷电生火;森林草木自燃生火;露天煤的自燃起火;偶然摩擦生火。火的使用对原始人类的生存和进化有什么作用? 火的作用有:①照明,从而扩大生活领域。②御寒。③熟食。熟食缩短了消化过程,有利于摄取食物营养,促进人类体质,尤其是大脑的发展和健康。④火可以帮助人们驱逐野兽,增强人类自卫和狩猎能力。 3、河姆渡原始居民比北京人、山顶洞人在生产生活上有了哪些进步? 河姆渡原始居民已使用磨制石器,用耒耜耕地,种植水稻,他们住着干栏式的房子,过上定居的生活。已挖掘水井,饮水更加方便。还饲养了家畜,会制造陶器,并能制作简单的玉器和原始乐器。 4、半坡聚落和河姆渡聚落的异同。 相同点:半坡聚落和河姆渡聚落都是新石器时代文化的典型代表,两者都开始了农业生产和定居生活,普遍使用磨制石器和陶器。

不同点:两者所处的地理环境不同,半坡聚落位于黄河流域,而河姆渡聚落位于长江流域;房屋的结构不同,前者为半地穴式房屋,后者为干栏式房屋。半坡聚落主要种植粟,而河姆渡聚落主要种植水稻。 5、半坡的房子与河姆渡的房子为什么不一样?半坡遗址处于黄河流域,冬季比较寒冷,夏季炎热,半地穴式的房屋冬暖夏凉。 河姆渡居民处于长江中下游地区,气候温暖湿润。干栏式建筑,以木结构为主。这种房屋利于通风防潮结论:这一方面反映了自然条件对远古居民生活的影响,也说明远古居民认识适应自然和利用改造自然的能力得到提高。 6、河姆渡、半坡、大汶口三处遗址的共同点。 1、都是原始农耕文化的遗址: 2、都出土了栽培作物种子; 3、都出土了“新石器”(磨制石器)和陶器; 4、都发现了家畜(chù)家禽(qín)的骨头。 7、想一想,人类走出洞穴盖房定居有什么重大意义? 走出洞穴盖房定居,使人们进一步人类摆脱了对自然的依赖,改善了生存环境,扩大了活动空间,提高了生活质量。 8、大汶口墓葬的差异反映了什么历史现象? 原始农耕社会后期,贫富已明显分化,人与人之间社会地位已有明显差异。 9、从陶舟的大小看,无实用价值。小陶舟是做什么用的?它说

消费者行为三大定律

消费者行为“三大铁律”及其它 2004-8-27 美国市场战略协会的创始人托马·J·温宁格认为,领先的公司必须能够创造出一种价值,一种使产品能够获取完全价格的价值。透过对消费者行为的研究发现,很多产品的畅销都是与消费者的感知价值密不可分。而这种价值具体现在消费者行为的两大类动机上:生理性购买动机和心理性购买动机。前者与维持和发展生命有机体相关,具有经常性、重复性和习惯性;后者与人们的心理活动中认识、情感和意志三个过程的统一密切相关,具有冲动性、新奇性和多样性等。在众多的市场表现上心理性消费显得格外的活跃,是众多企业营销挖掘的重点。无论从汽车、家电等耐用品,到服饰、日常用品及快速消费品,都概莫能外。 消费者购买行为的“三大铁律”诠释 现实的市场营销实践证明,满足人们的生理性需求是有限的,而满足心理需求则是无限的。消费者的生理性需求是相对稳定的,消费者的心理需求则是快速变化的,当原有产品不能满足新的心理需求时,就会受到新的购买冲击,从而使购买频率大大加快。因此,适度的引导,通过挖掘消费心理需求,提升感受价值是可以发现市场的机会,创造无限的空间。无数的营销实践证明: 消费者并不真正知道自己需要什么。现代消费者已不再是单纯意义上的物质消费者,而是一个整体消费、完整的感性消费者。厂商们通过产品的“感性价值”来建立差异化的竞争优势。众所周知,娃哈哈纯净水,仅仅就是一种干净的可饮水,由于赋予其感性的诉求,使其饮料类产品卖遍大江南北。传统的市场营销研究基于在已知的、现存的信息上的判断,而忽略了未来可能的变化。索尼公司的领导人盛田昭夫曾这样说过:我们的计划是用新产品引导公众,而不是问他们想要哪种产品。公众不知道能有什么,可我们知道。因此,我们不搞大量的市场顾客研究,而是去完成自己对产品的构想,并通过教育公众、与公众交流等方式设法为产品创造市场。所以说消费具有可诱导性,即需求是可以引导的。营销的核心任务就是在挖掘并满足现有消费需求的基础上,不仅要超越顾客需求期望,而且要经常预测顾客未来有什么新的期望,引导期望能够期望,最后控制期望,创造市场。 消费者并不需要产品信息真相。众多的市场试验证明消费是一种感觉,一种体验。这种感觉为心理性的消费带来了市场挖掘的机会和空间。化妆品。保健品等卖的是一种希望和期待。比如所有的洗发用品广告选的形象代言人,理性思考都知道是先有代言人的美发,而后有洗发用品。但在选购产品时几乎都是受广告的宣传诱导而选购,此类案例不胜枚举。既然消费者进行消费决策往往依据其直觉。喜好、售点现场的氛围诱导,那么营销活动的重心就是如何挖掘消费者关注的利益点,而不完全是产品本身。使消费者所购买的产品与消费者心理需求产生共鸣,形成有(无)形产品与消费心理互动,一旦这种心理产品同消费者的感性需求产生共鸣,就会令消费者产生强烈的购买欲望。因此,厂商们只

《设计概论》考试大纲及习题含答案

《设计概论》 考试大纲及练习 学生姓名: 学生身份证号: 学生准考证号: 完成作业时间:

设计概论考试大纲 一、课程性质 《设计概论》主要研究和概述设计现象、设计基本原理、设计基本规律等问题的一门课程,是艺术设计专业学生必修的理论基础课程。 二、学习目的 通过学习,让学生较全面地掌握设计的基本理论,树立正确的设计思想,完善知识结构,提高学生的设计文化修养和吸收前人,他人的设计成果的能力,扩展艺术思路,使理论与实践相结合,发挥重要作用。 三、学习要求 (一)导论:了解作为理论修养和基础课程的《设计概论》的重要性。 (二)设计的历史:较系统地了解设计历史发展的过程,熟练掌握各历史阶段出现的代表作品,设计现象和设计流派。能分析重要设计现象、设计流派出现的社会原因和背景,分析设计与艺术的关系、中国的设计文化如何确立等问题,并能在实践中吸收前人成果,拓展设计思路。 (三)设计的特征:较全面地认识设计文化和各种特征。理解并掌握设计的本质特征、设计的物化、设计文化的继承方式,装饰的意义和特点、视觉在设计中的意义和特性,美感的特征及材料和技术的重要性等重要问题。 (四)设计的思维:较系统的了解设计思维规律及其过程。理解并掌握知识的内在性、外在性、设计观念形成的特点、设计方法、设计过程的步骤和展示的重要性等问题,了解误区的产生和修正。(五)设计的形态:较全面地了解各种设计形态。较好地掌握视觉传达设计、公共艺术设计、工业产品设计、手工业设计各形态的概念和特征等,理解、分析环境与人的关系,手工业设计的重要性等问题,了解计算机设计的优势和前景。 (六)设计的市场:较好地了解从调研定位、创意策划、方案实施到投入市场的全过程的有关问题。掌握调研定位,创意策划的应用范围,构思灵感和文案整理,客户代理,市场规律及有关法规等内容。

水力学实验报告思考题答案(想你所要)..

实验二不可压缩流体恒定流能量方程(伯诺利方程)实验 成果分析及讨论 1.测压管水头线和总水头线的变化趋势有何不同?为什么? 测压管水头线(P-P)沿程可升可降,线坡J P可正可负。而总水头线(E-E)沿程只降不升,线坡J 恒为正,即J>0。这是因为水在流动过程中,依据一定边界条件,动能和势能可相互转换。测点5至测点7,管收缩,部分势能转换成动能,测压管水头线降低,Jp>0。测点7至测点9,管渐扩,部分动能又转换成势能,测压管水头线升高,J P<0。而据能量方程E1=E2+h w1-2, h w1-2为损失能量,是不可逆的,即恒有h w1-2>0,故E2恒小于E1,(E-E)线不可能回升。(E-E) 线下降的坡度越大,即J越大,表明单位流程上的水头损失越大,如图2.3的渐扩段和阀门等处,表明有较大的局部水头损失存在。 2.流量增加,测压管水头线有何变化?为什么? 有如下二个变化: (1)流量增加,测压管水头线(P-P)总降落趋势更显著。这是因为测压管水头 ,任一断面起始时的总水头E及管道过流断面面积A为定值时,Q增大, 就增大,则必减小。而且随流量的增加阻力损失亦增大,管道任一过水断面上的总水头E相应减 小,故的减小更加显著。 (2)测压管水头线(P-P)的起落变化更为显著。 因为对于两个不同直径的相应过水断面有 式中为两个断面之间的损失系数。管中水流为紊流时,接近于常数,又管道断面为定值,故Q增大,H亦增大,(P-P)线的起落变化就更为显著。 3.测点2、3和测点10、11的测压管读数分别说明了什么问题? 测点2、3位于均匀流断面(图2.2),测点高差0.7cm,H P=均为37.1cm(偶有毛细影响相差0.1mm), 表明均匀流同断面上,其动水压强按静水压强规律分布。测点10、11在弯管的急变流断面上,测压管水头差为7.3cm,表明急变流断面上离心惯性力对测压管水头影响很大。由于能量方程推导时的限制条件之一是“质量力只有重力”,而在急变流断面上其质量力,除重力外,尚有离心惯性力,故急变流断面不能选作能量方程的计算断面。在绘制总水头线时,测点10、11应舍弃。 4.试问避免喉管(测点7)处形成真空有哪几种技术措施?分析改变作用水头(如抬高或降低水箱的水位)对喉管压强的影响情况。 下述几点措施有利于避免喉管(测点7)处真空的形成: (1)减小流量,(2)增大喉管管径,(3)降低相应管线的安装高程,(4)改变水箱中的液位高度。

设计概论练习题

第一章设计概述 第一节设计含义与元素 一、填空题 1.“设计”的英文“design”一词,最早可追溯到拉丁语“desegnare”其意为。 2.古汉语“设计”是之意,并不是一个艺术概念。 3.绘画与科学据现有资料最早提出“工艺美术”这个词的是蔡元培,它在1920年的一文中写道“美术有狭义的、广义的,狭义的是专指建筑造像雕刻图画与美食工艺等。 4.广义的设计是一种人类对秩序和规律的渴望和冲动。 5. 是有意味的形式,是最能表达人类的情绪和感情的形式。 二、选择题 1.艾维斯色相环的三原色不包括() A. 蓝 B. 绿 C. 黄 D. 红 2.工艺美术运动的创始人是() A. 沃特·格罗皮乌斯 B. 米斯·凡·德·罗 C. 威廉·莫里斯 D. 维克多·巴巴纳克 3. 是为了展现空间的总体势或者突出空间的主题而创造的空间先后次序组合关系() A. 动线 B. 序列 C. 主轴线 D. 动态线 4. 又称质感或质地,是物质表面所呈现出来的色彩、光泽、纹理、粗细、厚薄、透明度等多种外面特性的综合表现。 A. 触觉 B. 肌理 C. 感觉 D. 明度 5. 是界定一种颜色时所用的名字,它指的是颜色最单纯的状态,是色彩特质的基础; A. 色相 B. 肌理 C. 纯度 D. 明度 三、名词解释 1. 动线 2.主轴线 3. 序列 4.艾维斯色相环 5.孟塞尔色彩理论 四、简答题 1.简述线条在设计中的作用。 2.简述二维平面幻想空间的营造方法。

3.简述色彩性质和色彩关系。 4.简述材料的特质。 第二节设计思维与方法 一、填空题 1.创造性思维的特征有。 2.设计思维主要有三大类型。 3.设计中有时会迸发出灵感和直觉,在心理学的研究中被称为或,灵感的出现常常给人们渴求已久的智慧之光。 4.设计思维是科学思维的和艺术思维的的有机整合。 二、选择题 1. 是抽象思维和形象思维、发散思维和聚合思维、顺向思维和逆向思维、横向思维和纵向思维等多种思维方式的协调统一。() A.创造性思维 B.理性思维 C. 感性思维 D. 逻辑思维 2.与创造性思维关系更紧密的是() A. 抽象思维 B.形象思维 C. 感性思维 D. 逻辑思维 3. 通过中常用的归纳和演绎、分析和综合等方法,设计可以得到理性的指导,从而使创意具有独特的视角,挖掘潜在的市场需求,引起受众的共鸣。() A. 抽象思维 B. 形象思维 C. 感性思维 D. 逻辑思维 4. 是以整体分析及系统观点来解决各种领域中具体问题的科学方法。 A. 头脑风暴法 B. 艺术论方法 C. 系统论方法 D. 功能论方法 5. 是把产品的功能问题放在设计活动的重要位置,在产品功能分析中排除一切不必要的多余的成分,从而达到降低成本的目的。 A. 头脑风暴法 B. 艺术论方法 C. 系统论方法 D. 功能论方法 三、名词解释 1.联想 2.设计创意 3.头脑风暴法 4.艺术论方法 5.系统论方法 四、简答题 1.简述设计思维中的科学思维和艺术思维,以及它们的作用方式。 2.创造性思维如何催生设计创意?

相关文档