文档库 最新最全的文档下载
当前位置:文档库 › The U.S. Federal Debt Outlook_ Reading th

The U.S. Federal Debt Outlook_ Reading th

The U.S. Federal Debt Outlook_ Reading th
The U.S. Federal Debt Outlook_ Reading th

专业茶农之家https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/ 茶农之家-茶农门户,服务广大茶农 https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/
The U.S. Federal Debt Outlook: Reading the Tea Leaves
Oya Celasun and Geoffrey Keim
专业茶农之家https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/ 茶农之家-茶农门户,服务广大茶农

专业茶农之家https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/ 茶农之家-茶农门户,服务广大茶农 https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/
2010 International Monetary Fund
WP/10/62
IMF Working Paper Western Hemisphere Department The U.S. Federal Debt Outlook: Reading the Tea Leaves1 Prepared by Oya Celasun and Geoffrey Keim Authorized for distribution by Charles Kramer March 2010 Abstract This Working Paper should not be reported as representing the views of the IMF.
The views expressed in this Working Paper are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily represent those of the IMF or IMF policy. Working Papers describe research in progress by the author(s) and are published to elicit comments and to further debate.
We show that fiscal policies reflecting a primary balance response to higher debt in line with historic experience would significantly increase the likelihood of reaching the debt targets of the U.S. administration in the medium term. Deficits and debt are higher under current budgetary proposals and IMF projections for real activity and interest rates, which do not include a reaction of policies to rising primary deficits. Under the IMF staff’s current economic projections, a primary fiscal adjustment of about 3.5 percent of GDP would be needed to achieve a debt level of about 70 percent of GDP in 2020. JEL Classification Numbers: E62, H68 Keywords: Public debt, fiscal sustainability, fan charts Author’s E-Mail Address: ocelasun@https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,; gkeim@https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,
1
The authors thank Charlie Kramer, David Robinson, and Martin Sommer for useful comments.
专业茶农之家https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/ 茶农之家-茶农门户,服务广大茶农

专业茶农之家https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/ 茶农之家-茶农门户,服务广大茶农 https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/
2
Contents
Page
I. Introduction ....................................................................................................................3 II. Federal Budget Projections—The Historic Record .......................................................4 III. Historic Fiscal Policy Behavior in the United States: How do Policy Makers Respond to Debt and Economic Cycles .......................................................................7 IV. The OMB’s and IMF’s Budget Projections for 2009–20 ..............................................9 V. Stochastic Simulations of Federal Government Debt Held by the Public ...................11 VI. Conclusions ..................................................................................................................13
Figures 1. U.S. Federal Debt Held by the Public (percent of GDP) ...............................................4 2. Fiscal and Economic Forecast Errors ............................................................................6 3. GNP/GDP Forecast Errors and Deficit Forecast Errors ................................................7 4. Actual and Predicted Primary Balances, 1949–2008 .....................................................9 5. Debt Profile Under Projected Primary Surplus Behavior (percent of GDP) ...............12 6. Debt Profile Under Historic Primary Surplus Behavior (Percent of GDP) .................13 Text Tables 1. Determinants of the Primary Balance ............................................................................8 2. Primary Deficit and Debt under Staff’s Baseline Projection and under Historic Primary Surplus Behavior ..........................................................................10 References ..........................................................................................................................15 Appendix: Debt Reduction after the Second World War ..................................................16
专业茶农之家https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/ 茶农之家-茶农门户,服务广大茶农

专业茶农之家https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/ 茶农之家-茶农门户,服务广大茶农 https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/
3 I. INTRODUCTION The publicly held debt of the U.S. federal government rose sharply in 2008 and 2009 due to the decline in economic activity, and discretionary measures to stimulate the economy and stabilize financial markets. Looking ahead, the path of U.S. federal government is subject to an unusual degree of uncertainty, partly because of the continued large risks affecting the economy and partly because the future course of fiscal policies are uncertain. The Administration has put a forth a wide array of fiscal policy proposals in the FY 2010–11 budgets but many of these proposals are yet to be legislated by the U.S. Congress. Current federal debt projections vary greatly across forecasters reflecting the significant disagreement on the economic outlook and the future path of fiscal policies (Figure 1).2 Past experience with official budget forecasts portrays a record of large deviations between projections and outturns, given the inherent difficulty of predicting future policies and economic conditions. Against this backdrop, carefully assessing the risk profile of debt projections is important since the public debt outlook has potential implications for borrowing costs in the United States and abroad, and limits the set of feasible future fiscal policies.3
2
The staff’s fiscal projections are based on the Administration’s FY 2011 budget proposal adjusted for differences in the staff’s versus the Office and Management and Budget’s macroeconomic projections.
3
The empirical literature suggests that an increase in publicly held U.S. federal debt of one percent of GDP raises long-term real U.S. Treasury debt yields by 2-5 basis points. See, for instance, Laubach (2007) and Engen and Hubbard (2004). A number of studies, in turn, suggest that emerging market sovereign bond yields increase with U.S. government debt yields.
专业茶农之家https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/ 茶农之家-茶农门户,服务广大茶农

专业茶农之家https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/ 茶农之家-茶农门户,服务广大茶农 https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/
4
Figure 1. U.S. Federal Debt Held by the Public (percent of GDP)
110 IMF 110
90
90
70
OMB
70
50
50
30 Projections 10 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010
Sources: Office of Management and Budget and Fund staff estimates.
30
10
This paper has two objectives—to evaluate the fiscal uncertainty stemming from economic conditions, and to compare debt profiles under different assumptions regarding future fiscal policies. The paper quantifies the uncertainty surrounding medium-term debt projections using fan charts—frequency distributions for debt over the horizon 2011–20— based on empirically plausible constellations of shocks to real output and interest rates. The fan charts are used to evaluate debt profiles under two alternative assumptions for the evolution of the primary balance: the primary balance path implied by the President’s FY 2011 Budget Proposal versus a primary balance path implied by estimated past fiscal policy adjustments to changing debt levels and the output gap. The rest of the paper is structured as follows. Section II provides an overview of the past record of budget and economic projections. Section III presents historic estimates of a primary surplus reaction function. Section IV presents fan charts of federal debt held by the public for the 2011–20 periods. Section V discusses the policy implications of the analysis.
II. FEDERAL BUDGET PROJECTIONS—THE HISTORIC RECORD There are two sources of official federal budget projections in the United States. The Office of Management and Budget (OMB) annually presents projections of the federal budget and debt through for the next five to ten years (and updates them in the summer under the Mid-Session Review). The Congressional Budget Office (CBO) also estimates the deficit and debt implications of the President’s budgetary proposals. The CBO additionally produces biannual “baseline” projections of the Federal budget under the assumed continuation of current laws and policies (i.e., not taking into account any
专业茶农之家https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/ 茶农之家-茶农门户,服务广大茶农

专业茶农之家https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/ 茶农之家-茶农门户,服务广大茶农 https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/
5 proposals that are yet to be legislated). None of these projections are meant to provide an objective prediction of fiscal balances in the medium-term, but rather projections under particular sets of policy and economic assumptions. Yet, they are the main sources of information available to the public on the likely future course of the fiscal path, and are, hence, closely watched. The IMF’s fiscal projections usually take the President’s Budget Proposal as a starting point, making adjustments for differences in underlying economic assumptions and for the likelihood of the enactment of various policies, where appropriate. The past record of budget projections shows a strong tendency for “optimistic” budget forecasts. Comparing fiscal outturns to the OMB’s budget projections from the initial year of each presidential term since 1977, one observes a much larger frequency of cases where the medium-term budget surplus was overestimated and the level of future debt was underestimated (Figure 2). The key exceptions are the budget projections made in fiscal years 1993 and 1997, partially reflecting an unexpected turnaround in economic activity after those years. While errors in predicting future real GDP have been significant contributors to budget forecast errors, they leave a large part of the variation in budget forecast errors unexplained. A scatter plot of budget and real GDP forecast errors show that large errors in projecting future economic activity tends to correlate with large errors in projecting future balances (Figure 3). However, a simple regression of budget projection errors on real GDP and CPI inflation forecast errors can explain only about 12 percent of the variation in budget errors, with CPI projection errors not contributing systematically to budget projection errors. That is, the evolution of future discretionary fiscal policy actions—and not just the automatic response of the budget balance to the economic cycle—have led to significant deviations of budget balances from their previously projected levels. Taken together, these stylized facts highlight the benefits of quantifying and assessing both the economic and fiscal policy risks surrounding public debt projections, as a complement to the deterministic projections that derive debt paths from a given set of policy actions embedded in the proposed budget. For instance, budgetary projections can be combined with empirically-realistic probability distributions for key economic variables to yield probability distributions for future debt under current policy proposals. Alternatively, probability distributions for economic variables could be augmented with behavioral assumptions for future policies. One possible augmentation would be a primary surplus reaction function estimated from past policy behavior. Combined with stochastic forecasts of macroeconomic variables, such a fiscal policy reaction function could be used to judge current policy proposals in terms of their implications for the future expected debt profile. The following sections provide such stochastic analysis.
专业茶农之家https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/ 茶农之家-茶农门户,服务广大茶农

专业茶农之家https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/ 茶农之家-茶农门户,服务广大茶农 https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/
6
Figure 2. Fiscal and Economic Forecast Errors
Deficit
5 0 -5 -10 -15 1974 100 (percent of GDP; fiscal years) 80 60 40 20 0 1974 1981 1988 1995 2002 2009 2016 1977 Actual 1982 1993 1997 1990 20 1980 2001 0 2005 2009 IMF Forecast 80 60 40 1981 1988 1995 2002 2009 2016 100 (percent of GDP; fiscal years) 1990 1977 1982 1986 1993 5 2001 0 2005 2009 -5 Actual IMF Forecast -10 -15
1980
Debt Held by the Public
Real GDP
150 (indexes, t-1 = 100) 140 -6.2 130 120 110 100 90 1977 1980 1982 1986 1990 1993 1997 2001 2005 2010 -11.2 -11.0 -3.1 -7.2 1.8 6.3 -3.6 -6.7 140 130 120 110 100 90 150
Consumer Prices
220 (indexes, t-1 = 100) 200 180 160 140 120 100 1977 1980 1982 1986 1990 1993 1997 2001 2005 2010 24.5 17.6 -19.6 200 180 160 1.1 5.0 -2.2 -2.4 4.2 140 120 100 220
-1.6
Note: Forecasts are compared to data collected from historical vintages and are not the currently published series. This method helps to limit the role new methodologies or revised data have on the forecast errors. Sources: Budget of the Federal Government (various years), Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis' ALFRED database, Bureau of Economic Analysis, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Haver Analytics, and Fund staff calculations.
专业茶农之家https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/ 茶农之家-茶农门户,服务广大茶农

专业茶农之家https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/ 茶农之家-茶农门户,服务广大茶农 https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/
7
Figure 3. GNP/GDP Forecast Errors and Deficit Forecast Errors
4 2 4 2 0 -2 -4 -6
1 year 4 years 7 years 10 years 2 Years 5 years 8 years 3 years 6 years 9 years
Deficit Forecast Error (percent of GDP)
0 -2 -4 -6 -8
-8 -10
-10 -8.0
-6.0
-4.0 -2.0 0.0 GNP/GDP Forecast Error (percent)
2.0
4.0
Note: Forecasts are compared to data collected from historical vintages and are not the currently published series. This method helps to limit the role new methodologies or revised data have on the forecast errors. Sources: Budget of the Federal Government (various years), Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis' ALFRED database, Bureau of Economic Analysis, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Haver Analytics, and Fund staff calculations.
III. HISTORIC FISCAL POLICY BEHAVIOR IN THE UNITED STATES: HOW DO POLICY MAKERS RESPOND TO DEBT AND ECONOMIC CYCLES? The most relevant past episode to the current fiscal outlook is the aftermath of the Second World War, when a combination of strong real economic growth, low real interest rates and primary surpluses brought about an impressive reduction in federal debt held by the public (see the Appendix). Current circumstances are unlikely to lead to strong real growth in the near-to-medium term, underscoring the importance of future primary surpluses in bringing down debt.4
4
See Barrerra, Estevao, and Keim (2009) for an analysis of U.S. potential GDP growth prospects.
专业茶农之家https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/ 茶农之家-茶农门户,服务广大茶农

专业茶农之家https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/ 茶农之家-茶农门户,服务广大茶农 https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/
8
Table 1. Determinants of the Primary Balance
Lag of debt as a percent of GDP Contemporaneous output gap as percent of GDP Constant 0.039 ** [0.015] 0.310 *** [0.083] -1.717 ** [0.658] 0.28 1948-2008 60
R-squared Observation period Number of observations
Notes: Standard errors are shown in brackets. *** and ** denote significance at the 1% and 5% levels, respectively. Ordinary least squares estimation. Dependent variable, the unified Federal Government Primary Balance as a percent of GDP.
Systematic evaluations of fiscal balances suggest that federal primary budget balances in the United States have historically increased rapidly in response to higher debt and the deviation of real GDP from potential output.5 A simple estimated fiscal reaction function for the period 1949–2008 suggests that the primary balance has risen on average by 0.039 percent of GDP for a one percentage point of GDP increase in debt held by the public (Table 1). This result can be interpreted as indicating policymakers have bolstered public finances in response to increases in debt, and suggests that fiscal policy has on average been responsible.6 In addition, the primary balance has on average increased by 0.310 percentage points of GDP in response to a one percentage point increase in the deviation of output from potential, illustrating the sensitivity of the federal government balance to economic conditions. Notably, however, actual surpluses exceeded the predicted levels quite significantly in most of the 1990s, but fell short of the model predictions over most of the 2000s (Figure 4). Hence, while such an estimated reaction function is not necessarily the best predictor of the policy path in any given point in time, it has the advantage of summarizing the long-run historic tendency in primary surplus behavior, and can be used as a benchmark for generating debt projections.
5
See for instance, Bohn (1998). This specification follows the base specification in Bohn (1998), who uses a somewhat different measure of cyclical variations in output and also includes a measure of temporary government spending. Estimating the reaction function over more recent time periods results in comparable coefficient estimates. Bohn (1998) shows that a positive coefficient on lagged debt in the primary balance reaction function would rule out an unstable debt path in the long-term (but a small coefficient would mean that debt stabilizes at a high level). The magnitude of the coefficient we estimate, 0.039 percent of GDP for each percentage point of GDP increase in debt, exceeds the average differential between ex-post real interest rates and growth in the United States ( e.g., 0.018 over 1985-99), which implies that the stabilization would be quite rapid if policymakers follow the reaction function.
6
专业茶农之家https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/ 茶农之家-茶农门户,服务广大茶农

专业茶农之家https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/ 茶农之家-茶农门户,服务广大茶农 https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/
9
Figure 4. Actual and Predicted Primary Balances, 1949-2008 (percent of GDP)
6 6
3
3
0
0
-3 Predicted Actual -6 1949 1954 1959 1964 1969 1974 1979 1984 1989 1994 1999 2004
Sources: Office of Management, Haver Analytics, and Budget and Fund staff estimates.
-3
-6
IV. THE OMB’S AND IMF’S BUDGET PROJECTIONS FOR 2009–20 The OMB remains significantly more optimistic than IMF staff on the overall future path of the recovery. For instance, the differential between real interest rates on new borrowing and real GDP growth—a key determinant of the rate of debt accumulation—is projected by OMB at about half a percentage point or less over the medium term, while IMF staff projections put the projected differential at about 2 percentage points. IMF staff make projections for U.S. federal government deficits by making adjustments to OMB’s budget projections on the basis of the differential between staff’s and OMB’s assumptions on future real GDP growth, the GDP deflator, and interest rates on Treasury debt (of three-month and ten-year maturities). The elasticities IMF staff use to determine how budgetary outcomes will differ from those projected by the OMB on the basis of deviations in economic variables were chosen to broadly replicate the OMB’s sensitivity analysis for revenues and expenditures to key economic variables (The President’s FY 2010 Budget Proposal, Analytical Perspectives, Table 12–4). Adjusted to reflect the IMF staff’s economic projections, the FY 2011 budget proposal would push federal debt held by the public to about 105 percent of GDP by 2020.7 Revenues would be slightly lower than projected by the OMB, but expenditures would be
7
The Administration’s FY 2011 budget projects debt to reach levels comparable to those that would be obtained under the assumption of historical fiscal behavior, but with much less primary fiscal effort.
专业茶农之家https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/ 茶农之家-茶农门户,服务广大茶农

专业茶农之家https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/ 茶农之家-茶农门户,服务广大茶农 https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/
10 significantly higher reflecting the higher costs of debt service and the inherently slow response of entitlement expenditures to changes in the path of real GDP growth. As discussed in more detail in the next section, the policy proposals under the FY 2011 budget would lead to a significantly higher level of debt than the path of primary surpluses implied by historical policy behavior. Under the staff’s baseline macroeconomic projections, if primary balances from 2012 onwards were to follow the relationship estimated in Section III using historical data, debt would stabilize immediately around 68 percent of GDP (Table 2). That is, if the rising debt levels lead policymakers to respond by adjusting fiscal policy early, with a magnitude consistent with the behavior observed in the past, upward pressures on debt would diminish significantly. If instead policymakers gradually shift toward policies implied by the estimated historic reaction function over the period 2012–20, debt would stabilize slightly above 80 percent of GDP in the medium term. While that adjustment path represents a significant improvement over the baseline path under the FY2011 budget proposal, it would still leave debt at a suboptimally high level in the medium term.
Table 2. Primary Deficits and Debt under Staff's Baseline Projection and under Historic Primary Surplus Behavior
(percent of GDP; fiscal years) 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 Primary deficit Staff's baseline based on FY 2011 budget Historic behavior (2012 onwards) Gradual shift towards historic behavior OMB budget projection Debt held by the public Staff's baseline based on FY 2011 budget Historic behavior (2012 onwards) Gradual shift towards historic behavior OMB budget projection 6.9 6.9 6.9 6.6 3.7 -0.7 2.8 3.0 2.8 -0.9 1.7 1.7 2.6 -0.9 1.1 1.1 2.9 -0.9 0.8 0.9 3.1 -0.9 0.4 0.7 2.9 -0.9 -0.1 0.5 2.7 -0.9 -0.6 0.2 2.9 -0.9 -1.0 0.5 2.9 -0.9 -1.5 0.7
69.3 69.3 69.3 69.3
73.2 68.7 72.3 71.0
76.6 68.2 74.5 71.9
80.2 68.0 76.5 72.3
84.3 67.8 78.3 72.9
88.6 67.7 79.8 73.6
93.0 67.7 80.9 74.2
97.3 101.9 106.8 67.7 67.8 68.0 81.5 81.8 81.7 74.8 75.9 77.2
Notes: Primary balances under historic behavior are calculated on the basis of the estimated reaction function shown in Table 1. Primary balances under a gradual shift toward historic behavior are given by the weighted average of the baseline IMF staff projection and the primary balance implied by the estimated historic reaction function. Under the gradual shift scenario, the weight on the primary balances derived from the historic reaction function is 0.2 in 2012 and smoothly rises to 1 in 2020. Sources: Office of Management and Budget and IMF staff estimates.
专业茶农之家https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/ 茶农之家-茶农门户,服务广大茶农

专业茶农之家https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/ 茶农之家-茶农门户,服务广大茶农 https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/
11 V. STOCHASTIC SIMULATIONS OF FEDERAL GOVERNMENT DEBT HELD BY THE PUBLIC To generate stochastic forecasts of the key variables driving debt dynamics, a vector autoregression (VAR) model is estimated for real GDP growth and real interest rates on three-month and 10-year Treasury debt covering the period 1953–2009. A large number of stochastic forecasts are then derived from the estimated equation system, with shocks to the variables sampled from the estimated joint error probability distribution.8 In a first step, we quantify the uncertainty around debt projections based on the FY 2011 budget. Stochastic forecasts of growth and real interest rates derived from the estimated VAR model, combined with the primary surplus path implied by the FY 2011 budget (adjusted for the differences between growth and interest rate forecasts underpinning the budget versus the staff’s baseline economic projections), underscore the significant degree of uncertainty stemming from the economic environment (Figure 5).9 Importantly, with more than 80 percent probability, debt in 2020 would be higher than the Administration’s projection of 77 percent of GDP.10 Further, with about 20 percent probability, debt would exceed staff’s baseline debt projection of about 105 percent of GDP for 2020.
8
For a description of the methodology see Celasun, Debrun, and Ostry (2006).
9
In this exercise, the primary balance path as a share of GDP is assumed to follow IMF staff’s baseline projections, but the interest rate/growth differential which determines interest costs follow the stochastic VAR forecasts.
The IMF staff’s baseline debt projection is higher than the mean path of the simulated debt distribution since the average economic forecast based on the VAR estimated over 1953-2009 is more favorable than the economic assumptions under the IMF staff’s baseline. VAR forecasts are likely to over-predict growth going forward, since they do not take into account the output loss associated with financial crises (documented, for instance, by Cerra and Saxena, 2008). The IMF’s GDP projection allows for a financial crisis effect.
10
专业茶农之家https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/ 茶农之家-茶农门户,服务广大茶农

专业茶农之家https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/ 茶农之家-茶农门户,服务广大茶农 https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/
12
Figure 5. Debt Profile Under Projected Primary Surplus Behavior (percent of GDP)
120 120
100
100
80
80
60
60
40
40
20 2006
2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
20 2020
Note: The dark cone in the center is the 20 percent standard error interval around the median projection, and the overall cone marks the 80 percent confidence interval. The solid red line shows the staff's baseline projection. Sources: Office of Management and Budget, Haver Analytics, and Fund staff estimates.
What would the debt profile look like if future primary balances instead followed patterns in historic primary surplus behavior, exhibiting a significant response to higher debt and output gaps? Combining the estimated historical primary surplus reaction function with stochastic forecasts of real GDP growth and real interest rates—and allowing for empirically realistic shocks to the primary surplus—imply a much more favorable median projection but slightly larger variation around the median path (reflecting the realistic uncertainty embedded into projected primary surplus behavior) (Figure 6).
专业茶农之家https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/ 茶农之家-茶农门户,服务广大茶农

专业茶农之家https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/ 茶农之家-茶农门户,服务广大茶农 https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/
13
Figure 6. Debt Profile Under Historic Primary Surplus Behavior (percent of GDP)
140 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 2006 140 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 2020
2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
Note: The dark cone in the center is the 20 percent standard error interval around the median projection, and the overall cone marks the 80 percent confidence interval. The solid red line shows the staff's baseline projection. Sources: Office of Management and Budget, Haver Analytics, and Fund staff estimates.
The results suggest that if the federal government on average adjusts the primary surplus as it has done in the past—implying a stronger improvement in the primary balance than under the staff’s baseline budget projections—the probability that debt in 2020 would exceed the Administration’s projection of 77 percent of GDP would be less than 40 percent. Notably, with more than 80 percent probability, debt would be lower than the level it would reach by 2020 under the IMF staff’s baseline.
VI. CONCLUSIONS Taking account of the joint stochastic distribution of real growth and real interest rates suggest significant uncertainty around the debt projections, with risks tilted toward a higher level of debt at the end of the forecast horizon, especially if primary surpluses do not rise to the same degree in response to rising debt as they have on average since 1949. Under the staff’s baseline economic projections for the January 2010 World Economic Outlook, stabilizing debt at about 70 percent of GDP over the 2015–20 period would require an adjustment of about 3.5 percent of GDP relative to the primary surplus path implied by the FY 2011 budget. With nondefense discretionary expenditures near historical lows and significant cuts in mandatory spending programs hard to achieve in the near term, most of the burden would need to fall on revenues, which on a general government basis are significantly lower than in most other large advanced economies.
专业茶农之家https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/ 茶农之家-茶农门户,服务广大茶农

专业茶农之家https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/ 茶农之家-茶农门户,服务广大茶农 https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/
14 Policymakers could stabilize debt rapidly if they set primary federal budget balances in line with the estimated historic fiscal reaction function. However, the change in the primary budget balance that would result from a switch to historic behavior would be significantly larger than any adjustment that has occurred since the end of World War II. But if the adjustment were delayed, then a sizable debt buildup as shown in the gradual adjustment scenario in Section IV would occur. The tension between the needs to maintain adequate stimulus before a durable recovery is achieved and to secure sustainability in the face of aging and crisis related fiscal pressures calls for a delicate balancing act. It has been suggested that curbing the future growth rate of health care costs and implementing readily available policy options to reduce future net social security expenditures would relieve this tension. It is certainly true that long-run fiscal finances not only in the United States but also in many other advanced economies are unsustainable in the absence of such reforms. However, it would be too optimistic to assume that solely relying on actions to cut future health and aging-related expenditures would be enough to avert the potentially negative implications of the future fiscal path on growth. Thus, it is important that a credible and sizable fiscal adjustment is undertaken once a sustainable recovery is firmly entrenched. There are two basic reasons that bolster this view. First, under current budgetary proposals, federal debt held by the public in the U.S. is set to double to 80 percent of GDP from its pre-crisis level in merely five years and will continue to rise without further fiscal action. Aging and health related spending are not the key drivers of this debt build-up. If the estimates of the interest effect of debt in the academic literature are taken at face value, such a rise in debt could add 100–200 basis points to long term government yields. It is hard to argue that allowing for a further expansion of debt from such levels would not pose risks to real growth; in fact the economic costs of raising taxes to keep debt at this level are likely to be far outweighed by the potential costs of inaction and uncertainty.11 Second, there are no well-understood and easy solutions to the problem of curbing health care costs—the most important factor in long run fiscal spending. As frequently emphasized by the CBO, serious reductions in the trajectory of costs could prove elusive and will require constant policy effort, experimentation, and immense political determination. Betting on the sure implementation and success of measures without creating space for maneuver in case of delays or failures would be risky. The uncertainty around potential actions to curb health care costs is a key reason why a medium run fiscal correction is needed—in addition to urgently taking the steps to address the entitlements problems—before the aging on the population makes the latter even more politically challenging.
Reinhart and Rogoff (2010) document that real growth is significantly lower when public debt exceeds 90 percent of GDP.
11
专业茶农之家https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/ 茶农之家-茶农门户,服务广大茶农

专业茶农之家https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/ 茶农之家-茶农门户,服务广大茶农 https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/
15 REFERENCES
Barrera, Natalia, Marcello Estevao, and Geoffrey Keim, 2009, “U.S. Potential Growth in the Aftermath of the Crisis,” United States: Selected Issues (Washington: International Monetary Fund). Bohn, Henning, 1998, “The Behavior of U.S. Public Debt and Deficits,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 113, No. 3, pp. 949–63. Celasun, Oya, Xavier Debrun, and Jonathan D. Ostry, 2006, “Primary Surplus Behavior and Risks to Fiscal Sustainability in Emerging Market Countries: A Fan Chart Approach”, IMF Staff Papers, Vol. 53 (3), pp. 401–25. Cerra, Valerie and Sweta C. Saxena, 2008, “Growth Dynamics: The Myth of Economic Recovery,” American Economic Review, March 2008, Vol. 98, No. 1, pp. 439–57. Reinhart, Carmen M., and Kenneth S. Rogoff, 2010, “Growth in a Time of Debt,” American Economic Review, May 2010, Vol. 100 No. 2.
专业茶农之家https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/ 茶农之家-茶农门户,服务广大茶农

专业茶农之家https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/ 茶农之家-茶农门户,服务广大茶农 https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/
16 APPENDIX. DEBT REDUCTION AFTER THE SECOND WORLD WAR U.S. federal debt held by the public climbed from 42 to 108 percent of GDP over the period 1941–46. It was brought down back to 42 percent of GDP in the subsequent seventeen years, by 1963. A very favorable real interest rate/growth dynamic and, to a lesser extent, primary fiscal surpluses, contributed to the debt reduction in the post-WWII era (Figure A1 and Table A1): The primary balance averaged 1.4 percent of GDP and was in surplus in 14 out of the 17 years between 1946 and 1963. All other factors—given by the change in debt minus the primary balance—made a large contribution to deficit reduction, averaging 2.5 percent of GDP over the 1946–63 period. This residual component is predominantly driven by the differential between interest rates and output growth, which was unusually low during that period mainly due to strong real growth as well as low long-term interest rates given the Fed’s interest rate pegging policy (which lasted until 1951).
Figure A1. Soures of Change in Federal Debt Held by the Public (percent of GDP)
40 30 20 10 0 -10 -20 1941 1946 1951 1956 1961
Sources: Office of Management and Budget and Fund staff estimates.
40
Real interest and growth differential, and other below-the line adjustments to debt Primary Deficit Change in Debt
30 20 10 0 -10 -20
专业茶农之家https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/ 茶农之家-茶农门户,服务广大茶农

专业茶农之家https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/ 茶农之家-茶农门户,服务广大茶农 https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/
17
Table A1. Sources of Change in Federal Debt Held by the Public
(percent of GDP; unless otherwise noted) Primary balance All other factors 1946-63 1963-84 1985-99 Memoranda: Real GDP growth* 1946-63 1963-84 1985-99 3.8 3.5 3.3 Real ten-year treasury bonds** 1.1 2.3 5.1 -1.4 0.5 -0.3 -2.5 -0.9 0.7
* Percent change, annual average. ** Percent, p.a. Notes: Real GDP growth data do not cover years prior to 1947. Real ex-post ten-year treasury bond rates are not available prior to 1952. Sources: Office of Management and Budget, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Haver Analytics, and Fund staff estimates
专业茶农之家https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,/ 茶农之家-茶农门户,服务广大茶农

163邮箱foxmail设置

163邮箱设置 1 · Outlook设置 2· Microsoft Outlook设置 3· Foxmail设置 Outlook 设置 请手动配置你的客户端: 1. 首先,启动Outlook Express。打开“Internet 连接向导”;首先输入你的“显示名”,如:163免费邮。此姓名将出现在你所发送邮件的“发件人”一栏。,然后单击“下一步”按钮; 2. 在“Internet 电子邮件地址”窗口中输入你的邮箱地址,如:username@16 https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,,再单击“下一步”按钮;

3. 在“接收邮件(pop、IMAP或HTTP)服务器:”字段中输入https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,。在“发送邮件服务器(SMTP):”字段中输入https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,,然后单击“下一步”; 4.在“帐户名:”字段中输入你的163免费邮用户名(仅输入@ 前面的部分)。在“密码:”字段中输入你的邮箱密码,然后单击“下一步”。

5.点击“完成”。 6.在Internet 帐户中,选择“邮件”选项卡,选中刚才设置的帐号,单击“属性”。

7.在属性设置窗口中,选择“服务器”选项卡,勾选“我的服务器需要身份验证”。 8.点击“确定”。 其它设置补充说明:

如果你希望在服务器上保留邮件副本,则在帐户属性中,单击“高级”选项卡。勾选“在服务器上保留邮件副本”。此时下边设置细则的勾选项由禁止(灰色)变为可选(黑色)。 恭喜!你已经完成Outlook 客户端配置,可以收发163 免费邮邮件了。

Microsoft Outlook 设置 请手动配置你的客户端: 1.打开Microsoft Outlook,点击“工具”,然后选“帐户”。 2.单击“添加”,在弹出菜单中选择“邮件”,进入Internet连接向导。 3.在“显示名:”字段中输入你的姓名,然后单击“下一步”。 4.在“电子邮件地址:”字段中输入你的完整163 免费邮地址(you@https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,) ,然后单击“下一步”。 5.在“接收邮件(pop、IMAP或HTTP)服务器:”字段中输入https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,。在“发送邮件服务器(SMTP):”字段中输入https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,,然后单击“下一步”。 6.在“帐户名:”字段中输入你的163免费邮用户名(仅输入@ 前面的部分)。在“密码:”字段中输入你的邮箱密码,然后单击“下一步”。 7.点击“完成”。 8.在Internet 帐户中,选择“邮件”选项卡,选中刚才设置的帐号,单击“属性”。 9.在属性设置窗口中,选择“服务器”选项卡,勾选“我的服务器需要身份验证”,并点击旁边的“设置”按钮。 10.登录信息选择“使用与接收邮件服务器相同的设置”,确保你在每一字段中输入了正确信息。 11.点击“确定”。 恭喜!你已经完成Outlook 客户端配置,可以收发163 免费邮邮件了。

中考语文课外阅读题小说题库

中考语文课外阅读题(小说)题库 (一) 我家最富的时刻 第二次世界大战前,我们家是城里唯一没有汽车的人家。我母亲安慰家里人说:“一个人有骨气,就等于有了一大笔财富。” 几个星期后,一辆崭新的别克牌汽车在街上展出了。这辆车已定在今夜以抽奖的方式馈赠给得奖者。当扩音器里大声叫着我父亲的名字,明白无误地表示这辆彩车已属于我们家所有时,我简直不相信这是事实。 父亲开着车缓缓驶过拥挤的人群,我几次想跳上车去,同父亲一起享受这幸福的时刻,却被父亲给赶开了。最后一次,父亲甚至向我咆哮:“滚开,别呆在这儿,让我清净清净!”我无法A 父亲的举动。当我回家后B 地向母亲诉说的时候,母亲似乎非常理解父亲。她C 我说:“不要烦恼,你父亲正在思考一个道德问题,我们等着他找到适当的答案。” “难道我们中彩得到的汽车是不道德的吗” “过来,孩子。”母亲温柔地说。 桌上的台灯下放着两张彩票存根,上面的号码分别是348和349,中彩号是348。“你能看出两张彩票有什么不同吗”母亲问。 我看了好几遍终于看到其中一张彩票的一角上有用铅笔写的淡淡的K字。 “这K字代表凯特立克。”母亲说。 “吉米·凯特立克,爸爸交易所的老板!”我有些不解。 “对。”母亲把事情一五一十地给我讲了。 当初父亲对吉米说,他买彩券时可以代吉米买一张,吉米嘟哝了一声:“为什么不可以呢”老板说完就去干自己的事了,国后可能再也没有想到过这件事。348那张是为凯特立克买的,可以看出那K字用大拇指轻轻擦过,但仍能看出淡淡的铅笔印。 对我来说,这是件简单的事。吉米·凯特立克是个百万富翁,拥有十几辆汽车,他不会计较这辆彩车。 “汽车应该归我爸爸!”我激动地说。 “你爸爸知道该怎么做的。”母亲平静地回答我。 不久,我们听到父亲进门的脚步声,又听到他在拨电话号码,显然电话是打给凯特立克的。第二天下午,凯特立克的两个司机来到我们这儿,把别克牌汽车开走了,他们送给我父亲一盒雪茄。 直到我成年以后,我们家才有了一辆汽车。随着时间的流逝,我母亲那一句“一个人有骨气,就等于有了一大笔财富”的话语具有了新的含义。回顾以往的岁月,我现在才明白,父亲打电话的时候是我家最富有的时刻。 1.给下列加点的字注音。 馈赠 ..()()彩券.() ..()()咆哮 2.在文中横线上填写适当的词语。 A.B.C. 3.文章题目的关键词语是什么其含义是什么对你有何启示 答: 。4.文章主要记叙了一件什么事(用简要的文字叙述) 答:。5.文中的“贫”指什么“富”又指什么 答:。(参考答案:1.Kuì zèng páo xiào quàn 2.理解委屈安慰3.关键词是“最富”;其含义是指道德品质的富有。启示:富有不仅指物质和金钱上的富有,更重要的是一个人道德品质的富有。4.主

古代晋灵公不君、齐晋鞌之战原文及译文

晋灵公不君(宣公二年) 原文: 晋灵公不君。厚敛以雕墙。从台上弹人,而观其辟丸也。宰夫胹熊蹯不熟,杀之,寘诸畚,使妇人载以过朝。赵盾、士季见其手,问其故而患之。将谏,士季曰:“谏而不入,则莫之继也。会请先,不入,则子继之。”三进及溜,而后视之,曰:“吾知所过矣,将改之。”稽首而对曰:“人谁无过?过而能改,善莫大焉。诗曰:‘靡不有初,鲜克有终。’夫如是,则能补过者鲜矣。君能有终,则社稷之固也,岂惟群臣赖之。又曰:‘衮职有阙,惟仲山甫补之。’能补过也。君能补过,衮不废矣。” 犹不改。宣子骤谏,公患之,使鉏麑贼之。晨往,寝门辟矣,盛服将朝。尚早,坐而假寐。麑退,叹而言曰:“不忘恭敬,民之主也。贼民之主,不忠;弃君之命,不信。有一于此,不如死也!”触槐而死。 秋九月,晋侯饮赵盾酒,伏甲将攻之。其右提弥明知之,趋登曰:“臣侍君宴,过三爵,非礼也。”遂扶以下。公嗾夫獒焉。明搏而杀之。盾曰:“弃人用犬,虽猛何为!”斗且出。提弥明死之。 初,宣子田于首山,舍于翳桑。见灵辄饿,问其病。曰:“不食三日矣!”食之,舍其半。问之,曰:“宦三年矣,未知母之存否。今近焉,请以遗之。”使尽之,而为之箪食与肉,寘诸橐以与之。既而与为公介,倒戟以御公徒,而免之。问何故,对曰:“翳桑之饿人也。”问其名居,不告而退。——遂自亡也。 乙丑,赵穿①攻灵公于桃园。宣子未出山而复。大史书曰:“赵盾弑其君。”以示于朝。宣子曰:“不然。”对曰:“子为正卿,亡不越竟,反不讨贼,非子而谁?”宣子曰:“呜呼!‘我之怀矣,自诒伊戚。’其我之谓矣。” 孔子曰:“董狐,古之良史也,书法不隐。赵宣子,古之良大夫也,为法受恶。惜也,越竞乃免。” 译文: 晋灵公不行君王之道。他向人民收取沉重的税赋以雕饰宫墙。他从高台上用弹弓弹人,然后观赏他们躲避弹丸的样子。他的厨子做熊掌,没有炖熟,晋灵公就把他杀了,把他的尸体装在草筐中,让宫女用车载着经过朝廷。赵盾和士季看到露出来的手臂,询问原由后感到很忧虑。他们准备向晋灵公进谏,士季说:“如果您去进谏而君王不听,那就没有人能够再接着进谏了。还请让我先来吧,不行的话,您再接着来。”士季往前走了三回,行了三回礼,一直到屋檐下,晋灵公才抬头看他。晋灵公说:“我知道我的过错了,我会改过的。”士季叩头回答道:“谁能没有过错呢?有过错而能改掉,这就是最大的善事了。《诗经》说:‘没有人向善没有一个开始的,但却很少有坚持到底的。’如果是这样,那么能弥补过失的人是很少的。您如能坚持向善,那么江山就稳固了,不只是大臣们有所依靠啊。

农田水利学试题及答案

农田水利学课程考试试题及答案 姓名年级专业学号 一、名词解释(每小题2分共10分) 1.灌水率: 2.排涝模数: 3.平均排除法: 4.(排涝计算中的)设计内水位: 5.容泄区: 二.选择题(共10分) 1.灌溉设计标准是反映灌区效益达到某一水平的一个重要技术指标,一般以( )与( )表示? A、灌溉设计保证率、抗旱天数。 B、水文年型、降水量。 C、设计灌溉用水量全部获得满足的年数、抗旱天数。 D、水源来水量、灌区需水量。 2.什么叫田间渠系的灌排相邻布置?() A、灌溉渠道与排水沟道的规划布置。 B、田间各级渠道规划布置的形式。 C、田间灌排渠系并行相邻的布置形式。 D、田间灌排渠系交错的布置形式。

3.渠道的输水损失包括以下四个部分:() A、干渠、支渠、斗渠及农渠等四级渠道的水量损失。 B、渠床土质、地下水埋深、渠道的工作制度及输水时间。 C、自由渗流、顶托渗流、渠床土质、与渠道的工作制度等。 D、渠道水面蒸发损失、渠床渗漏损失、闸门漏水与渠道退水等。 4.什么叫渠道水的利用系数?() A、灌溉渠系的净流量与毛流量的比值。 B、某一级渠道的净流量与毛流量的比值。 C、田间实际灌入的有效水量与末级渠道的供水量之比。 D、实际灌入农田的有效水量和渠首引入的水量之比。 5.在渠道规划设计中,渠道最小流量有何作用?() A、用以校核对下一级渠道的水位控制条件。 B、用以校核渠道不淤条件。 C、用以确定修建节制闸的位置。 D、用以校核对下一级渠道的水位控制条件和确定修建节制闸的位置,并按最小流量验算渠道不淤条件。 6.什么叫雨水径流集蓄灌溉工程?() A、导引、收集雨水径流,并把它蓄存起来加以有效灌溉利用的工程技术措施。 B、田面、坡面、路面及屋面庭院等各类集水工程。

foxmail中企业邮箱设置步骤

新浪企业邮箱设置——foxmail设置 提示:使用Foxmail收发邮件前,请首先查看您的Foxmail的版本号,如果您使用的版本低于3.11(3.1或更低),请到Foxmail 网站下载支持SMTP认证的Foxmail 3.11,并进行安装或升级;然后按照以下方法进行设置: 1、单击主菜单中的"帐户",选择"新建"菜单项打开Foxmail用户向导,如下图所示; 2、单击"下一步"按钮打开"建立新用户帐号"窗口,如下图所示,在用户名处填写您的名字,可以是真实姓名,也可以是代号,它将显示在Foxmail的主页面。同时指定您的邮件保存路径,一般选择默认路径;

3、单击"下一步"按钮打开"邮件身份标记"窗口,如下图所示,在"发送者姓名"处填写您的名字,可以是真实姓名,也可以是代号,它将出现在您所发送邮件的"寄件人"一栏中。在"邮件地址"处填写您的邮件地址,如:wu@https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,,它将使收信人知道您的地址并给您回信;

4、单击"下一步"按钮打开"指定邮件服务器"窗口,如下图所示,在“POP3服务器”处填写https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,,在“SMTP 服务器”处填写https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,,在“POP3帐户名”处填写您的邮件地址,如wu@https://www.wendangku.net/doc/cc16863654.html,,在"密码"处设定邮件服务器密码; 5、单击"下一步"按钮打开"帐户建立完成"提示页面,如下图所示,单击"完成"按钮关闭窗口,并回到Foxmail邮件夹页面,新建立的帐户将显示在Foxmail的主页面;

6、点击该帐户头像,然后单击主菜单中的"帐户",选择"属性"菜单项打开"帐户属性"对话框; 7、选择"邮件服务器"选项,勾选"SMTP服务器需要认证"前的勾选框,此时右侧的"设置"按钮由禁止(灰色)变为可选(黑色),如下图所示;

如何翻译古文

如何翻译古文 学习古代汉语,需要经常把古文译成现代汉语。因为古文今译的过程是加深理解和全面运用古汉语知识解决实际问题的过程,也是综合考察古代汉语水平的过程。学习古代汉语,应该重视古文翻译的训练。 古文翻译的要求一般归纳为信、达、雅三项。“信”是指译文要准确地反映原作的含义,避免曲解原文内容。“达”是指译文应该通顺、晓畅,符合现代汉语语法规范。“信”和“达”是紧密相关的。脱离了“信”而求“达”,不能称为翻译;只求“信”而不顾“达”,也不是好的译文。因此“信”和“达”是文言文翻译的基本要求。“雅”是指译文不仅准确、通顺,而且生动、优美,能再现原作的风格神韵。这是很高的要求,在目前学习阶段,我们只要能做到“信”和“达”就可以了。 做好古文翻译,重要的问题是准确地理解古文,这是翻译的基础。但翻译方法也很重要。这里主要谈谈翻译方法方面的问题。 一、直译和意译 直译和意译是古文今译的两大类型,也是两种不同的今译方法。 1.关于直译。所谓直译,是指紧扣原文,按原文的字词和句子进行对等翻译的今译方法。它要求忠实于原文,一丝不苟,确切表达原意,保持原文的本来面貌。例如: 原文:樊迟请学稼,子曰:“吾不如老农。”请学为圃。子曰:“吾不如老圃。”(《论语?子路》) 译文:樊迟请求学种庄稼。孔子道:“我不如老农民。”又请求学种菜蔬。孔子道:“我不如老菜农。”(杨伯峻《论语译注》) 原文:齐宣王问曰:“汤放桀,武王伐纣,有诸?”(《孟子?梁惠王下》) 译文:齐宣王问道:“商汤流放夏桀,武王讨伐殷纣,真有这回事吗?(杨伯峻《孟子译注》) 上面两段译文紧扣原文,字词落实,句法结构基本上与原文对等,属于直译。 但对直译又不能作简单化理解。由于古今汉语在文字、词汇、语法等方面的差异,今译时对原文作一些适当的调整,是必要的,并不破坏直译。例如: 原文:逐之,三周华不注。(《齐晋鞌之战》) 译文:〔晋军〕追赶齐军,围着华不注山绕了三圈。

李文忠《摆渡老人》中考现代文阅读练习及答案

(三)课外阅读(13分) 摆渡老人 李文忠 ①读中学时,学校设在邻村,与我们村有一条河隔着,便认识了那摆渡老人。 ②当时,那老人一直是我们取乐的对象。每到放学,肚子饿得直叫的我们便一窝蜂向渡口跑去,挤在那儿。渡船只要一近岸,大家便争先恐后地向船上跃去。虽然老人很有经验,未到岸边便做好回撑的准备,但超载和落水的事仍然时有发生。超载时,船上的,岸上的,都望着老人手忙脚乱的样子大笑。夏天下雨时,大家总是把伞迎着风,看着渡船被吹到离渡口好远的地方,老人一番折腾,将船撑到渡口,我们便哄笑着上了岸。 ③最有意思的要数冬天(当时我是这样认为的)。冬天很冷,河面结了一层厚厚的冰。每天早晨,当我们赶到渡口时,总看见老人在那边晃着船,好长时间,才把船晃过来。望着老人跳舞似的笨拙姿势,我们总是哄笑,一直到船靠岸。我们往往因此耽误了早读,但我们都挺愿意。于是就希望天再冷些,便可迟点起来,反正去早了也过不了河。我们都为找到一个偷懒的理由而感到高兴。当时的我们,是“心忧读书愿天寒”。 ④那一天特别冷,我因有事起了个早,吃过早饭后,便不紧不慢地向学校走去。到渡口时我惊奇地发现,那老人不是我预料的那样正在“跳舞”,却已经到了这边。我和他攀谈起来。我问他:“你今天怎么这么早?”老人咳嗽了一声,缓缓地说:“许是人老了,早上总起不来。昨天听学校说耽误了学生上早读,今天我就起了早。谁知等了好长时间,才来了你一个人。”说完,便送我过河。 ⑤船到河心,老人忽然回头对我说道:“你们小孩子可要好好读书啊。”那双眼中竟满含着期待和爱意,我心中一震,看着老人瘦弱的身体,沾满冰碴的白胡子,一双手冻得发紫,猛地问道:“你干啥要吃这份苦呢?”好久,老人长叹一声说道:“干啥?哎,以前我也有一个可爱的儿子,他曾吵着要上学,但终究没上成。后来他得病去了,我一直感到对不起他,我在这儿摆渡,接送你们上学,心里好受些。”谈话间,船已到岸。待我上岸后,老人把船向河那边撑去。看着老人的背影,我不再感到笨拙可笑,鼻子有些酸酸的。 ⑥那天,我把老人的故事讲给同学们听了。以后,我们上船再也没有起哄。于是老人饱经风霜的脸上出现了笑容。 ⑦再后来,两岸之间架起了一座桥。最后一次过河时,老人对我们说:“以后不再送你们过河了,你们要记住,好好读书。” ⑧“好好读书”,这句话一直留在我记忆中。 ⑨真想再见见摆渡老人。 20、本文具体描述了摆渡老人接送“我们”过河上学的辛劳。先写老人因“我们”的___________而手忙脚乱,一番折腾;再写因_________,老人好不容易“才把船晃过来”;最后写老人不顾自己__________,特地起大早送“我们”过河上学。(3分) 21.第⑤段中摆渡老人说“我在这儿摆渡,接送你们上学,心里好受些”。请你用自己的语言简要说说为什么老人觉得这样做“心里好受些”。(3分) ________________ 22.第⑤段中划横线的语句表现了“我”当时___________和___________的心情。(2分) 23.结合全文内容回答以下问题。 原先,摆渡老人在孩子们的眼里是一个________________的形象;后来,摆渡老人在孩子们的心中却是一个________________的形象。(2分) 24.“摆渡老人”中的“摆渡”可以理解为老人对“我们”生活、思想上的帮助。其实生活中还有许多这样的“摆渡者”,请你展开联想,按照下面的示例仿写两个句子。

齐晋鞌之战原文和译文

鞌之战选自《左传》又名《鞍之战》原文:楚癸酉,师陈于鞌(1)。邴夏御侯,逢丑父为右②。晋解张御克,郑丘缓为右(3)。侯日:“余姑翦灭此而朝食(4)”。不介马而驰之⑤。克伤于矢,流血及屦2 未尽∧6),曰:“余病矣(7)!”张侯曰:“自始合(8),而矢贯余手及肘(9),余折以御,左轮朱殷(10),岂敢言病吾子忍之!”缓曰:“自始合,苟有险,余必下推车,子岂_识之(11)然子病矣!”张侯曰:“师之耳目,在吾旗鼓,进退从之。此车一人殿之(12),可以集事(13),若之何其以病败君之大事也擐甲执兵(14),固即死也(15);病未及死,吾子勉之(16)!”左并辔(17) ,右援拐鼓(18)。马逸不能止(19),师从之,师败绩。逐之,三周华不注(20) 韩厥梦子舆谓己曰:“旦辟左右!”故中御而从齐侯。邴夏曰:“射其御者,君子也。”公曰:“谓之君子而射之,非礼也。”射其左,越于车下;射其右,毙于车中。綦毋张丧车,从韩厥,曰:“请寓乘。”从左右,皆肘之,使立于后。韩厥俛,定其右。逢丑父与公易位。将及华泉,骖絓于木而止。丑父寝于轏中,蛇出于其下,以肱击之,伤而匿之,故不能推车而及。韩厥执絷马前,再拜稽首,奉觞加璧以进,曰:“寡君使群臣为鲁、卫请,曰:‘无令舆师陷入君地。’下臣不幸,属当戎行,无所逃隐。且惧奔辟而忝两君,臣辱戎士,敢告不敏,摄官承乏。” 丑父使公下,如华泉取饮。郑周父御佐车,宛茷为右,载齐侯以免。韩厥献丑父,郤献子将戮之。呼曰:“自今无有代其君任患者,有一于此,将为戮乎”郤子曰:“人不难以死免其君,我戮之不祥。赦之,以劝事君者。”乃免之。译文1:在癸酉这天,双方的军队在鞌这个地方摆开了阵势。齐国一方是邴夏为齐侯赶车,逢丑父当车右。晋军一方是解张为主帅郤克赶车,郑丘缓当车右。齐侯说:“我姑且消灭了这些人再吃早饭。”不给马披甲就冲向了晋军。郤克被箭射伤,血流到了鞋上,但是仍不停止擂鼓继续指挥战斗。他说:“我受重伤了。”解张说:“从一开始接战,一只箭就射穿了我的手和肘,左边的车轮都被我的血染成了黑红色,我哪敢说受伤您忍着点吧!”郑丘缓说:“从一开始接战,如果遇到道路不平的地方,我必定(冒着生命危险)下去推车,您难道了解这些吗不过,您真是受重伤了。”daier 解张说:“军队的耳朵和眼睛,都集中在我们的战旗和鼓声,前进后退都要听从它。这辆车上还有一个人镇守住它,战事就可以成功。为什么为了伤痛而败坏国君的大事呢身披盔甲,手执武器,本来就是去走向死亡,伤痛还没到死的地步,您还是尽力而为吧。”一边说,一边用左手把右手的缰绳攥在一起,用空出的右手抓过郤克手中的鼓棰就擂起鼓来。(由于一手控马,)马飞快奔跑而不能停止,晋军队伍跟着指挥车冲上去,把齐军打得打败。晋军随即追赶齐军,三次围绕着华不注山奔跑。韩厥梦见他去世的父亲对他说:“明天早晨作战时要避开战车左边和右边的位置。”因此韩厥就站在中间担任赶车的来追赶齐侯的战车。邴夏说:“射那个赶车的,他是个君子。”齐侯说: “称他为君子却又去射他,这不合于礼。”daier 于是射车左,车左中箭掉下了车。又射右边的,车右也中箭倒在了车里。(晋军的)将军綦毋张损坏了自己的战车,跟在韩厥的车后说: “请允许我搭乗你的战车。”他上车后,无论是站在车的左边,还是站在车的右边,韩厥都用肘推他,让他站在自己身后——战车的中间。韩厥又低下头安定了一下受伤倒在车中的那位自己的车右。于是逢丑父和齐侯(乘韩厥低头之机)互相调换了位置。将要到达华泉时,齐侯战车的骖马被树木绊住而不能继续逃跑而停了下来。(头天晚上)逢丑父睡在栈车里,有一条蛇从他身子底下爬出来,他用小臂去打蛇,小臂受伤,但他(为了能当车右)隐瞒了这件事。由于这样,他不能用臂推车前进,因而被韩厥追上了。韩厥拿着拴马绳走到齐侯的马前,两次下拜并行稽首礼,捧着一杯酒并加上一块玉璧给齐侯送上去,

农田水利学试题及答案资料

农田水利学课程考试试题及答案 姓名 年级 专业 学号 一、名词解释(每小题 2 分 共 10 分) 1. 灌水率: 2. 排涝模数: 3. 平均排除法: 4. (排涝计算中的)设计内水位: 5. 容泄区: 二.选择题(共 10 分) 1. 灌溉设计标准是反映灌区效益达到某一水平的一个重要技术指标,一般以 ( )与 ( )表示? A 、灌溉设计保证率、抗旱天数。 B 、水文年型、降水量。 C 、设计灌溉用水量全部获得满足的年数、抗旱天数。 D 、水源来水量、灌区需水量。 2. 什么叫田间渠系的灌排相邻布置? ( ) 3. 渠道的输水损失包括以下四个部分: ( ) A 、干渠、支渠、斗渠及农渠等四级渠道的水量损失。 B 、渠床土质、地下水埋深、渠道的工作制度及输水时间。 C 、自由渗流、顶托渗流、渠床土质、与渠道的工作制度等。 D 、渠道水面蒸发损失、渠床渗漏损失、闸门漏水与渠道退水等。 4. 什么叫渠道水的利用系数? ( ) A 、灌溉渠系的净流量与毛流量的比值。 B 、某一级渠道的净流量与毛流量的比值。 C 、田间实际灌入的有效水量与末级渠道的供水量之比。 D 、实际灌入农田的有效水量和渠首引入的水量之比。 5. 在渠道规划设计中,渠道最小流量有何作用? ( ) A 、用以校核对下一级渠道的水位控制条件。 A 、灌溉渠道与排水沟道的规划布置。 B 、田间各级渠道规划布置的形 式。

B、用以校核渠道不淤条件。 C、用以确定修建节制闸的位置。 D、用以校核对下一级渠道的水位控制条件和确定修建节制闸的位置,并按最小流量验算渠道不淤条件。 6.什么叫雨水径流集蓄灌溉工程?() A 、导引、收集雨水径流,并把它蓄存起来加以有效灌溉利用的工程技术措施。 B、田面、坡面、路面及屋面庭院等各类集水工程。 C、各类形式的水窖、水窑窖等蓄水工程。 D、各类最为有效节水的灌溉方式。 7.集流面的处理主要包括哪三类方法?() A 、采用混凝土、水泥土、三七灰土进行表面处理。 B、采用塑料薄膜、或塑膜复沥青、复草泥。 C、植被管理;地表处理;化学处理。 D、采用钠盐、硅有机树脂及粗石蜡等化学处理方法。 8.蓄水工程有哪几种主要的类型?() A 、引水渠沟或管道、入水口、拦污栅、沉沙槽、蓄水设施以及放水装置等。 B、涝池、旱井、田间蓄水池、水窖、水窑窖等。 C、引水渠、蓄水窑洞与放水暗管与放水暗渠。 D 、沉沙池、进水管、水窖等。 9.什么叫续灌方式?() A 、类似于自来水管道可随机用水的供水方式。 B、输配水管道进行输水、配水和灌水的方式。 C、是指上一级管道按预先划分好的轮灌组分组向下一级管道配水的方式。 D 、是指上一级管道向所有的下一级管道同时配水的方式。 10.什么叫集水效率?() A 、降水特征(次降雨量、降雨强度)和集水面质地、坡度、前期含水量与集水面尺寸。 B、集水面的处理材料、集水面积、集流路径和汇流时间。 C、随降水强度的增大而提高。 D、某时段内或某次降雨集水面的集水量占同一时期内的降雨量的比值。 三、简答题(每题6分,共30分) 1.四种地表取水方式的使用条件

摆渡老人的阅读答案

摆渡老人的阅读答案 摆渡老人 ①读中学时,学校设在邻村,与我们村有一条河隔着,便认识了那摆渡老人。 ②当时,那老人一直是我们取乐的对象。每到放学,肚子饿得直叫的我们便一窝蜂向渡口跑去,挤在那儿。渡船只要一近岸,大家便争先恐后地向船上跃去。虽然老人很有经验,未到岸边做好回撑的准备,但超载和落水的事仍然时有发生。超载时,船上的,岸上的,都望着老人手忙脚乱的样子大笑。夏天下雨时,大家总是把伞迎着风,看着渡船被吹淌到离渡口好远的地方,老人一番折腾,将船撑到渡口,我们便哄笑着上了岸。 ③最有意思的要数冬天。冬天很冷,河面结了一层厚厚的冰。每天早晨,当我们赶到渡口时,总看见老人在那边晃着船,好长时间,才把船晃过来。望着老人跳舞似的笨拙姿势,我们总是哄笑,一直到船靠岸。我们往往因此耽误了早读,但我们都挺愿意。于是就希望天再冷些,便可迟点起来,反正去早了也过不了河。我们都为找到一个偷懒的理由而感到高兴。当时的我们,是心忧读书愿天寒。 ④那一天特别冷,我因有事起了个早。吃过早饭后,便不紧不慢地向学校走去。到渡口时我惊奇地发现,那老人不

是我预料的那样正在跳舞,却已经到了这边。我和他攀谈起来。我问他:你今天怎么这么早?老人咳嗽了一声,缓缓地说:许是人老了,早上总起不来。昨天听学校说耽误了学生上早读,今天我就起了早。谁知等了好长时间,才来了你一个人。说完,便送我过河。 ⑤船到河心,老人忽然回头对我说道:你们小孩子可要好好读书啊。那双眼中竟满含着期待和爱意。我心中一辱,看着老人瘦弱的身体,沾满冰碴的白胡子,一双手冻得发紫,猛地问道:你干啥要吃这份苦呢?好久,老人长叹一声说道:干啥?哎,以前我也有一个可爱的儿子,他曾吵着要上学,但终究没上成。后来他得病去了,我一直感到对不起他,我在这儿摆渡,接送你们上学,心里好受些。谈话间,船已到岸。待我上岸后,老人又把船向河那边撑去。看着老人的背影,我不再感到笨拙可爱,鼻子有些酸酸的。 ⑥那天,我把老人的故事讲给同学们听了。以后,我们上船再也没有起哄。于是老人饱经风霜的脸上出现了笑容。 ⑦再后来,两岸之间架起了一座桥。最后一次过河时,老人对我们说:以后不再送你们过河了,你们要记住,好好读书。 ⑧好好读书,这句话一直留在我记忆中。 ⑨真想再见见摆渡老人。 13、本文具体描述了摆渡老人接送我们过河上学的辛劳。

《鞌之战》阅读答案(附翻译)原文及翻译

《鞌之战》阅读答案(附翻译)原文及翻 译 鞌之战[1] 选自《左传成公二年(即公元前589年)》 【原文】 癸酉,师陈于鞌[2]。邴夏御齐侯[3],逢丑父为右[4]。晋解张御郤克,郑丘缓为右[5]。齐侯曰:余姑翦灭此而朝食[6]。不介马而驰之[7]。郤克伤于矢,流血及屦,未绝鼓音[8],曰:余病[9]矣!张侯[10]曰:自始合,而矢贯余手及肘[11],余折以御,左轮朱殷[12],岂敢言病。吾子[13]忍之!缓曰:自始合,苟有险[14],余必下推车,子岂识之[15]?然子病矣!张侯曰:师之耳目,在吾旗鼓,进退从之[16]。此车一人殿之[17],可以集事[18],若之何其以病败君之大事也[19]?擐甲执兵,固即死也[20]。病未及死,吾子勉之[21]!左并辔[22],右援枹而鼓[23],马逸不能止[24],师从之。齐师败绩[25]。逐之,三周华不注[26]。 【注释】 [1]鞌之战:春秋时期的著名战役之一。战争的实质是齐、晋争霸。由于齐侯骄傲轻敌,而晋军同仇敌忾、士气旺盛,战役以齐败晋胜而告终。鞌:通鞍,齐国地名,在今山东济南西北。 [2]癸酉:成公二年的六月十七日。师,指齐晋两国军队。陈,

列阵,摆开阵势。 [3]邴夏:齐国大夫。御,动词,驾车。御齐侯,给齐侯驾车。齐侯,齐国国君,指齐顷公。 [4]逢丑父:齐国大夫。右:车右。 [5]解张、郑丘缓:都是晋臣,郑丘是复姓。郤(x )克,晋国大夫,是这次战争中晋军的主帅。又称郤献子、郤子等。 [6]姑:副词,姑且。翦灭:消灭,灭掉。朝食:早饭。这里是吃早饭的意思。这句话是成语灭此朝食的出处。 [7]不介马:不给马披甲。介:甲。这里用作动词,披甲。驰之:驱马追击敌人。之:代词,指晋军。 [8] 未绝鼓音:鼓声不断。古代车战,主帅居中,亲掌旗鼓,指挥军队。兵以鼓进,击鼓是进军的号令。 [9] 病:负伤。 [10]张侯,即解张。张是字,侯是名,人名、字连用,先字后名。 [11]合:交战。贯:穿。肘:胳膊。 [12]朱:大红色。殷:深红色、黑红色。 [13]吾子:您,尊敬。比说子更亲切。 [14]苟:连词,表示假设。险:险阻,指难走的路。 [15]识:知道。之,代词,代苟有险,余必下推车这件事,可不译。 [16]师之耳目:军队的耳、目(指注意力)。在吾旗鼓:在我们

农田水利学试题六

农田水利学课程考试试题 姓名年级专业学号 一、名词解释(每小题2分共10分) 1、渠道设计流量: 2、灌溉水利用系数: 3、最小流量: 4、田间净流量:: 5、不冲流速: 二.单向选择题(共10分) 1.地下水临界深度是指? () A、地下水埋藏深度。 B、在一定的自然条件和农业技术措施条件下,为了保证土壤不产生渍害,所要求保持的地下水最小埋深。 C、在一定的自然条件和农业技术措施条件下,为了保证土壤不产生盐碱化和作物不受盐害,所要求保持的地下水最小埋深。 D、在一定的自然条件和农业技术措施条件下,为了保证土壤不产生盐碱化和作物不受盐害,所要求保持的地下水最大埋深。 2.对于控制一定地下水位要求的农田排水系统,下列哪种说法是正确的?() A、在同一排水沟深度的情况下,排水沟的间距愈大,地下水位下降速度愈快,在一定时间内地下水位的下降值愈大,在规定时间内地下水位的下降值也愈大。 B、在允许的时间内要求达到的地下水埋藏深度ΔH一定时,排水沟的间距愈大,需要的深度也愈大。 C、在允许的时间内要求达到的地下水埋藏深度ΔH一定时,排水沟的间距愈小,需要的深度也愈大。 D、在同一排水沟间距的情况下,排水沟的深度愈小,地下水位下降速度愈快,在一定时间内地下水位的下降值愈大,在规定时间内地下水位的下降值也愈大。

3.设计排涝标准时,需选择发生一定重现期的暴雨,一般选择标准是?() A、1-5年。 B、5-10年。 C、10-15年。 D、15-20年。 4.对渍害最不敏感的作物是?() A、小麦; B、玉米; C、高粱; D、水稻。 5.特别适宜防治土壤次生盐碱化的农田排水方式是?() A、明沟排水; B、竖井排水; C、暗管排水; D、暗沟排水。 6.在进行排水沟设计时,用来校核排水沟的最小流速的设计流量是?() A、排涝设计流量; B、排渍设计流量; C、日常排水设计流量; D、排涝模数。 7.农田长期渍水不会造成下列后果? A、土壤的透气性很差。 B、土层都处于强烈的氧化状态。 C、利于硫化氢等硫化物的形成,对作物根系产生永久性伤害。 D、有机质矿化程度低,分解释放的有效养分少,不能满足作物生长的需要。 8.防治土壤盐碱化的水利技术不包括?() A、明沟排水 B、井灌井排 C、灌水冲洗 D、放淤改良 9.什么叫计划用水?() A、灌溉水量的分配方法。 B、就是按作物的需水要求与灌溉水源的供水情况,结合渠系工程状况,有计划地蓄水、引水、配水与灌水。 C、是指灌溉水在灌区各级渠系调配、管理的方式。 D、是指灌溉水通过各级渠道流入田间的方法。 10.灌区用水计划一般来说有哪四种主要类型?() A、水源引水计划、渠系配水计划与田间的用水计划等。 B、水权集中、统筹兼顾、分级管理、均衡受益。 C、年度轮廓用水计划、某灌季全渠系用水计划、干支渠段用水计划及用水单位的用水计划。 D、上下结合、分级编制,统一调度、联合运用。

摆渡老人阅读题答案

摆渡老人阅读题答案 读中学时学校与我们村隔着一条河由此认识了那摆渡老人。当时那老人一直是我们取乐的对象。每到放学肚子饿得直叫的我们便一窝蜂向渡口跑去挤在那儿。渡船只要一靠近岸大家便争先恐后地向船上跃去。虽然老人很有经验来到岸边便做好回撑的准备但超载和落水的事仍然时有发生。超载时船上的岸上的都望着老人手忙脚乱的样子大笑。夏天下雨时大家总是把伞迎着风看着渡船被吹到离渡口好远的地方老人一番折腾将船撑到渡口我们便哄笑着上了岸。 最有意思的要数冬天。冬天很冷河面结了一层厚厚的冰。每天早晨当我们赶到渡口时总看见老人在那边摇着船好长时间才把船摇过来。一直到船靠岸。我们往往因此耽误了早读但我们都挺愿意。于是就希望天再冷些便可迟点起来反正去早了也过不了河。我们都为找到一个偷懒的理由而感到高兴。当时的我们是“心忧读书愿天寒”。 那一天特别冷我因有事起了个早。吃过早饭后便不紧不慢地向学校走去。到渡口时我惊奇地发现那老人不是我预料的那样正在“跳舞”却已经到了这边。我和他攀谈起来。我问他“你今天怎么这么早”老人咳嗽了一声缓缓地说“许是人老了早上总起不来。昨天听学校说耽误了学生上早读今天我就起了早。谁知等了好长时间才来了你一个人。”说完便送我过河。 船到河心老人忽然回头对我说“你们小孩子可要好好读书啊。”那双眼睛竟满含着期待和爱意。我心中一震看着老人疲弱的身体沾满水碴?6?7碴á?6?8小碎块。的白胡子一双冻得发紫的手猛地问到“你干啥要受这份苦呢”好久老人长叹一声说道“干啥哎以前我也有一个可爱的儿子他曾吵着要上学但终究没上成。后来他得病去了我一直感到对不起他。我在这儿摆渡接送你们上学心里好受些。”谈话间船已到岸。待我上岸后老人又把船向河那边撑去。看着老人的背影我不再感到笨拙可笑鼻子有些酸酸的。 那天我把老人的故事讲给同学们听了。以后我们乘船再也没有起哄。于是老人饱经风霜的脸上现出了笑容。 再后来两岸之间架起了一座桥。最后一次过河时老人对我们说“以后不再送你们过河了你们要记住好好读书啊。” “好好读书”这句话一直留在我的记忆中。 真想再见见摆渡老人。 1本文具体描述了摆渡老人接送“我们”过河上学的辛劳。先写老人因“我们”的______而手忙脚乱一番折腾再写因 ______老人好不容易“才把船晃过来”最后写老人不顾自己________特地起大早送“我们”过河上学。用概括的语言填空 2第⑤段中摆渡老人说“我在这儿摆渡接送你们上学心里好受些”。请你用自己的语言简要说说为什么老人觉得这样做“心里好受些”。分析摆渡老人的心理答______________________________________________________ 3第⑤段中加粗的词句表现了“我”当时_______和_______的心情。 4原先摆渡老人在孩子们的眼里是一个______的形象后来摆渡老人在孩子们的心中却是一个______的形象。用自己的话填空5“摆渡老人”中的“摆渡”可以理解为老人对“我们”生活、思想上的帮助。其实生活中还有许多这样的“摆渡者”请你展开联想按照下面的示例仿写三个句子。新题型示例1作家把读者摆渡到精神的彼岸。 训练联想和表达能力 2 “希望工程”把贫穷的孩子摆渡到求知的校园。 仿句1______________________________________________________

《鞌之战》阅读答案附翻译

《鞌之战》阅读答案(附翻译) 《鞌之战》阅读答案(附翻译) 鞌之战[1] 选自《左传·成公二年(即公元前589年)》 【原文】 癸酉,师陈于鞌[2]。邴夏御齐侯[3],逢丑父为右[4]。晋解张御郤克,郑丘缓为右[5]。齐侯曰:“余姑 翦灭此而朝食[6]。”不介马而驰之[7]。郤克伤于矢, 流血及屦,未绝鼓音[8],曰:“余病[9]矣!”张侯[10]曰:“自始合,而矢贯余手及肘[11],余折以御,左轮 朱殷[12],岂敢言病。吾子[13]忍之!”缓曰:“自始合,苟有险[14],余必下推车,子岂识之[15]?——然 子病矣!”张侯曰:“师之耳目,在吾旗鼓,进退从之[16]。此车一人殿之[17],可以集事[18],若之何其以 病败君之大事也[19]?擐甲执兵,固即死也[20]。病未 及死,吾子勉之[21]!”左并辔[22],右援枹而鼓[23],马逸不能止[24],师从之。齐师败绩[25]。逐之,三周 华不注[26]。 【注释】 [1]鞌之战:春秋时期的著名战役之一。战争的实质是齐、晋争霸。由于齐侯骄傲轻敌,而晋军同仇敌忾、 士气旺盛,战役以齐败晋胜而告终。鞌:通“鞍”,齐

国地名,在今山东济南西北。 [2]癸酉:成公二年的六月十七日。师,指齐晋两国军队。陈,列阵,摆开阵势。 [3]邴夏:齐国大夫。御,动词,驾车。御齐侯,给齐侯驾车。齐侯,齐国国君,指齐顷公。 [4]逢丑父:齐国大夫。右:车右。 [5]解张、郑丘缓:都是晋臣,“郑丘”是复姓。郤(xì)克,晋国大夫,是这次战争中晋军的主帅。又称郤献子、郤子等。 [6]姑:副词,姑且。翦灭:消灭,灭掉。朝食:早饭。这里是“吃早饭”的意思。这句话是成语“灭此朝食”的出处。 [7]不介马:不给马披甲。介:甲。这里用作动词,披甲。驰之:驱马追击敌人。之:代词,指晋军。 [8]未绝鼓音:鼓声不断。古代车战,主帅居中,亲掌旗鼓,指挥军队。“兵以鼓进”,击鼓是进军的号令。 [9]病:负伤。 [10]张侯,即解张。“张”是字,“侯”是名,人名、字连用,先字后名。 [11]合:交战。贯:穿。肘:胳膊。 [12]朱:大红色。殷:深红色、黑红色。 [13]吾子:您,尊敬。比说“子”更亲切。

扬州大学农科农田水利学计算题过程及答案

农田水利学计算题 1、某小型灌区作物单一为葡萄,某次灌水有600亩需灌水,灌水定额为25m 3/亩,灌区灌溉水利用系数为0.75,试计算该次灌水的净灌溉用水量和毛灌溉用水量。 解:W 毛=MA/η水=25*600/0.75=20000(m3) W 净=MA=25*600=15000(m3) 2、某灌区A =0.2万亩,A 蔬菜=0.16万亩,A 花卉=0.04万亩,m 蔬菜=20m 3/亩,m 花卉=15m 3/亩。求综合净灌水定额m 综及净灌溉用水量。 解:m 综=α1m 1+α2m 2=0.8*20+0.2*15=16+3=19(m3/亩) W=m 综*A=19*2000=38000(m3) 3、某小型提水灌区,作物均为果树,面积1000亩,用水高峰期最大灌水定额为25m3/亩,灌溉水利用系数为0.75,灌水延续4天,每天灌水20小时。试计算水泵设计流量。 解:Q 设= =25*1000/(3600*20*4*0.75)=0.12(m3/s ) 4、已知苏南某圩区,F=3.8Km2,其中旱地占20%,水田占80%。水田日耗水e=5mm/d ,水田滞蓄30mm ,旱地径流系数为0.6 。排涝标准采用1日暴雨200mm ,2天排除,水泵每天工作时间22小时。试求泵站设计排涝流量Q 和综合设计排涝模数q 。 解:R 水田=P-h 田蓄-eT=200-30-5*2=160(mm ) 水ηTt A m t T W Q k j j ij i i i 360036001∑==??=

R旱田=αP=0.6*200=120(mm) ∴Q=(R水田F水田+R旱田F旱田)/3.6Tt =(160*3.8*0.8+120*3.8*0.2)/3.6*2*22 =3.65(m3/s) ∴q =Q/F=3.65/3.8=0.96(m3/km2) 5、冬小麦播前土壤最大计划湿润层深度为0.6m,土壤平均孔隙率42.5%(占土壤体积百分比),土壤田间持水率为70%(孔隙百分比)。播前土壤含水率为45.0%(孔隙百分比)。计算冬小麦的播前灌水定额。解:M=667Hn(θmax-θ0)=667*0.6*0.425*(0.7-0.45) =42.5(m3/亩) 6、已知某渠系如图1-4-3所示,干、支渠采用续灌,设计灌水率q=0.78m3/(s·万亩),一支灌溉面积为2万亩,二支灌溉面积为2.4万亩,三支灌溉面积2.5万亩,支渠的灌溉水利用系数为0.82,干渠渠道水利用系数0.9。 【要求】 (1)计算各支渠设计流量; (2)计算干渠设计流量和灌区灌溉水利用系数。 解:(1)Q1=qA1/η支水=0.78*2/0.82=1.90(m3/s) Q2=qA2/η支水=0.78*2.4/0.82=2.28(m3/s) Q3=qA3/η支水=0.78*2.5/0.82=2.38(m3/s) (2)η水=η支水*η干=0.82*0.9=0.74 7、1)下图渠系干、支渠续灌

四年级阅读理解专题(含答案)

阅读理解专题(含答案) 一、四年级语文阅读理解练习 1.阅读短文,回答问题。 从前,有一对夫妻,开了一家酒铺,由于他们的酒物美价廉,生意十分兴隆。 有一天,丈夫外出,妻子偷偷地在酒里掺了水,多卖了五元钱。 晚上丈夫回来,妻子得意地把自己的“秘诀”告诉了丈夫,以为会得到丈夫的夸奖。谁知,丈夫一听,急得双脚直跳,抱着头痛苦地说:“哎!你把我们最值钱的东西,只五元就卖掉了!” 果然,从此他们的生意一日不如一日,最后终于彻底破产。当妻子贫困交加、奄奄一息的时候,她流着泪,悔恨地说:“我明白了……” (1)在文中找出与“红火”意思相近的一个词语,这个词语是:________。 (2)根据意思,在短文中找词语。 ①价格便宜,货物又好。________ ②形容气息微弱。________ (3)丈夫认为“我们最值钱的东西”是什么? (4)给短文的结尾补上“妻子”说的话。 我明白了________。 【答案】(1)兴隆 (2)物美价廉;奄奄一息 (3)诚信。 (4)略 【解析】【分析】(1)红火的意思是形容旺盛、热闹。根据意思从文中选择即可。(2)解答本题首先理解给出的词语的解释,根据意思从文中找出相应的词语即可。(3)解答本题首先要仔细阅读语段,抓住语段中关键性的语句进行理解。 (4)补充句子:根据上文的意思把不完整的句子补充完整,使句子前后意思一致。联系具体语境对句子进行补充和续写。 【点评】(1)本题主要考查近义词的理解能力。做题时要先理解所给词语的意思,然后再从文中选出和它意思相近的词语。 (2)本题考查的是对词语意思的掌握,解答本题首先理解给出的词语的解释,在理解的基础上,从文中找出与它意思对应的词语。 (3)本题主要考查的是文章内容的理解能力。做题时要先理解文章的主要内容,再结合文章的主旨进行理解。 (4)这种类型的题,首先要仔细阅读并理解所给出的内容,再确定要补充的内容,写好之后读读是否符合文义。 2. 棉花里的父亲

河海农水试题1

河海大学2002年攻读硕士学位研究生入学考试试题 名称:农田水利学 一:名词解释(每小题4分) 1、作物需水量 2、喷灌强度 3、灌溉水利用系数 4、作物水分生产函数 5、排渍水位 6、排水承泄区 二、判断题(每小题2分,共20分) 1、土壤中的毛管水是不能被植物根系吸收利用的水分() 2、灌水定额是灌区的单位面积在单位时间内的灌水量() 3、水库取水方式适用于河道水位和流量都满足灌溉引水要求的情况() 4、规划固定式喷灌系统时,支管轮灌方式是否合理对于管的设计流量有显著影响() 5、设计灌溉渠道时,如果糙率系数取值偏小,就会使渠道断面偏小,从而影响渠道过水能力() 6、田间排水沟的间距取决于土壤性质和排水要求,和排水沟的深度无关() 7、排渍模数是排水渠单位面积的排渍流量() 8、灌溉渠道实行轮灌的主要目的在于减少渠道渗漏损失() 9、喷灌工程不适用于地面坡度变化复杂的农田使用() 10、用平均排出法计算的排涝设计流量比可能出现的排涝设计流量偏大() 三、问答题(每小题8分,共40分) 1、灌溉渠道的设计流量、加大流量、最小流量在渠道设计中各有什么用途? 2、排水沟道系统的规划布置要考虑哪些原则? 3、局部灌溉包括哪些类型?渠道衬砌有何优缺点? 4、渠道的水量损失包括哪些方面?渠道衬砌有何优缺点? 5、灌溉管道系统的工作制度包括哪些内容?各自的适用条件是什么? 河海大学2001年攻读硕士学位入学考试试题 名称:农田水利学 一:名词解释(每小题三分) 1. 凋萎系数2、作物需水量3、灌溉设计保证率 4、灌溉制度5、日常水位6、排水承泻区7、排渍模数8、轮灌 二、判断题(每小题而分) 对以下概念,你认为正确的在括号内填“+”号,你认为错误的在括号内填“-”号。 1、土壤中的吸湿水是可以被作物根系吸收利用的水分() 2、鉴定土壤水分对作物生长是否有效的主要标志是土壤含水量() 3、制定作物灌溉制度的基本原理是水量平衡() 4、从河道引水灌溉时,如果河道流量大于灌溉引水流量,但枯水期水位偏低,饮水不足,应修筑水库调节径流() 5、设计灌溉渠道时,如果糙率系数取值偏小,就会失渠道断面过大而增加工程量() 6、上层滞水是停留在包气带土壤中的重力水() 7、地下水的流量、流速、水位等运动要素随时间而变化的运动叫做地下水非稳定流动() 8、田间排水沟的间距取决于土壤性质和排水要求,与排水沟深度无关() 9、制定旱作物灌溉制度是作物地下水利用量指的是地面以下土层的储水量() 10、用平均排出法计算的排涝设计流量比可能出现的排涝设计流量偏大() 三、问答题(每小题6分)

相关文档