文档库 最新最全的文档下载
当前位置:文档库 › Does Public Financial News Resolve Asymmetric Information

Does Public Financial News Resolve Asymmetric Information

Does Public Financial News Resolve Asymmetric Information
Does Public Financial News Resolve Asymmetric Information

Does Public Financial News Resolve Asymmetric Information?

Paul C. Tetlock*

April 2010

Abstract

I use uniquely comprehensive data on financial news events to test four predictions from an asymmetric information model of a firm’s stock price. Certain investors trade on information before it becomes public; then public news levels the playing field for other investors, increasing their willingness to accommodate a persistent liquidity shock. Empirically, I measure public information using firms’ stock returns on news days in the Dow Jones archive. I find four return predictability and trading volume patterns following news that are consistent with the asymmetric information model’s predictions. Some evidence is, moreover, inconsistent with alternative theories in which traders have different interpretations of news for rational or behavioral reasons.

* Roger F. Murray Associate Professor of Finance at Columbia Business School. I thank Wes Chan, Kent Daniel, Larry Glosten, Amit Goyal, Gur Huberman, Charles Jones, Eric Kelley, Anthony Lynch, Chris Parsons, Paolo Pasquariello, Gideon Saar, Mark Seasholes, Matthew Spiegel, Avanidhar Subrahmanyam, Heather Tookes, two anonymous referees, and seminar participants at Columbia University, Global Alpha, the HKUST Asset Pricing Symposium, the NBER Microstructure meetings, the NY Fed, NYU, Princeton, UNC, and the WFA meetings for their comments. I am grateful to Dow Jones for providing access to their news archive. Please send comments to paul.tetlock@https://www.wendangku.net/doc/f4130496.html,.

This study uses 29 years of data on all publicly traded US firms in the Dow Jones news archive to examine how firms’ information environments change during 2.2 million news events. This is one of the largest quantitative records of financial news events ever constructed, allowing for a uniquely comprehensive analysis of the role of news in stock pricing. I propose and test a model of a firm’s stock price in which a public news story eliminates an information asymmetry between two groups of traders. Before the news, one investor group has superior information, but also incurs a persistent liquidity shock. Then the news story informs the relatively uninformed investor group, making them less wary of providing liquidity to the informed traders. Even so, because they are risk averse, the relatively uninformed investors do not fully accommodate the liquidity shock on the day of the news event. This theoretical model is similar to the Kim and Verrecchia (1991), Wang (1994), Holden and Subrahmanyam (2002), and Llorente, Michaely, Saar, and Wang (2002) (hereafter LMSW) models, but differs in its explicit assumptions about the role and timing of public news.

This paper’s contribution is to test four predictions from this model using uniquely comprehensive news data, along with firms’ stock returns and trading activity. This model’s first prediction is that the firm’s return on a news day positively predicts its returns after the news. The intuition is that the gradual dissipation of the liquidity shock after the news leads to return momentum. Second, returns on high-volume news days are better positive predictors of post-news returns than returns on low-volume news days. The reason is that news that resolves more asymmetric information facilitates more absorption of the pre-news liquidity shock, resulting in both higher trading volume at the time of news and higher return momentum after news.

Third, the contemporaneous correlation between the firm’s trading volume and the magnitude of its price changes temporarily increases around news days. As news occurs, both volume and price changes are driven by the belief revisions of uninformed investors because informed investors already know the news. The uninformed investors increase (decrease) their stock holdings when they learn from the news that the stock’s expected returns are higher (lower), producing a high correlation

between volume and the magnitude of price changes on news days. Fourth, the price impact of

informed trading in the firm’s stock temporarily decreases as news reduces information asymmetry.

I measure public news events using the entire Dow Jones (DJ) archive, which includes all DJ newswire and all Wall Street Journal (WSJ) stories about publicly traded US firms from 1979 to 2007. I compare stock returns and trading activity on news days and non-news days using daily cross-sectional regressions in the spirit of Fama and MacBeth (1973). This analysis produces four main results: 1) ten-day reversals of daily returns are 38% lower on news days; 2) ten-day volume-induced momentum in daily returns exists only on news days for many stocks; 3) the cross-sectional correlation between the absolute value of firms’ abnormal returns and abnormal turnover is temporarily higher by 35% on news days; and 4) the price impact of order flow is temporarily lower by 3.3% on news days. These four findings suggest that some traders have already acted on the information released by public news, whereas other traders use news to learn about expected returns. The second and third empirical findings are novel, whereas the first and fourth findings significantly extend previous results.1

Although these four qualitative results are robust over time and across stocks with different characteristics, the magnitudes of the effects vary substantially. News is a better predictor of reduced return reversal in small firms, which suggests that each news story conveys more information for these firms. The link between news and reduced return reversal is also stronger for stories that consist of many newswire messages and earnings-related words, which are plausible proxies for the information content of news.

For small stocks and illiquid stocks, volume-induced return momentum occurs only on news days, whereas volume-induced reversal occurs on other days. This could indicate that public news

resolves more asymmetric information in these firms. The correlation between absolute returns and

1 Karpoff (1987) and others find a robust positive correlation between volume and absolute price changes. Smirlock and Starks (1988) show that this relationship is particularly strong around earnings announcements for 300 firms spanning 49 trading days, but they do not investigate other news events.

volume declines by a larger amount following news stories that consist of many newswire messages and earnings-related words, and for small stocks and illiquid stocks. This suggests that the role of public information in resolving privately held differences in opinion is stronger for small stocks and illiquid stocks. Conversely, I find no clear evidence that news predicts return reversals, which are typically associated with the arrival of liquidity shocks. One interpretation is that the release of news coincides with information more often than it coincides with liquidity shocks.

Several empirical design choices minimize the likelihood that the results are spurious. First, I focus on weekly time horizons for return reversals because the evidence in Jegadeesh (1990) and Lehmann (1990) shows that weekly return reversals dominate one-day autocorrelations. In these tests, I skip day one to avoid microstructure biases, such as bid-ask bounce, that affect return correlations in consecutive periods.2

Second, I present the four main results for firms in the top and bottom size and liquidity quintiles separately based on the LMSW (2002) findings that these stocks’ information environments differ. Although the effects are often stronger for small and illiquid stocks, all four results hold in both groups. This demonstrates that the results are statistically robust and economically important. At the same time, the consistently stronger findings for small stocks and illiquid stocks hint at a role for information asymmetry. By contrast, the main results are never stronger and are sometimes actually weaker for stocks with high analyst forecast dispersion and low institutional ownership. This variation is inconsistent with several alternative theories in which investors interpret news differently for rational or irrational reasons, such as Kim and Verrecchia (1994) or Harris and Raviv (1993).

Third, I use daily cross-sectional regressions—in the spirit of Fama and MacBeth (1973)—to control for a wide range of influences on firms’ stock returns. The regressions simultaneously test the

2 Another benefit is that the holding period return excludes the positive one-day autocorrelation that Sias and Starks (1997) link to institutional ownership. It is possible that institutional order splitting across days causes two-day price pressure that reverses at longer horizons. Indeed, recent evidence in Kaniel, Saar, and Titman (2007) and Barber, Odean, and Zhu (2009) demonstrates that price pressure from trading clienteles develops and subsides over multi-week horizons. Accordingly, I explicitly analyze whether institutional ownership affects the results.

model’s first two predictions for expected returns, while controlling for other known well-known predictors of returns such as size, book-to-market, return momentum, return volatility, abnormal turnover, and several other variables. I present these regressions separately for firms that differ in alternative measures of the information environment such as analyst coverage to ensure that news is distinct from other proxies for information asymmetry.

This paper contributes to three literatures. One is the volume-induced return reversal literature, which includes a complex set of results. Whereas Conrad, Hameed, and Niden (1994) show that return reversals for relatively small Nasdaq stocks decrease with trading volume, Cooper (1999) shows that return reversals for larger NYSE stocks increase with trading volume. Avramov, Chordia, and Goyal (2006) find that volume-induced return reversal increases with stock illiquidity. I confirm that large stocks and liquid stocks exhibit volume-induced momentum, whereas small stocks and illiquid stocks exhibit unconditional volume-induced reversals. I find, however, that small stocks and illiquid stocks actually exhibit volume-induced return momentum on public news days, just as large stocks and liquid stocks do on all days. The findings here complement the volume-induced reversal findings in LMSW (2002). Whereas LMSW (2002) do not directly measure firms’ information environments, I analyze the impact of public news releases on volume-induced and unconditional return reversals. I also investigate how the correlation between absolute returns and volume changes and how price impact changes around public news events. The upshot is that I provide new evidence on how investors obtain information that is relevant for firm valuation and which public signals resolve information asymmetries across investors.

This paper also contributes to a growing literature on the impact of public news releases, which includes Stickel and Verrecchia (1994), Pritamani and Singal (2001), Chan (2003), Chae (2005), Vega (2006), Chava and Tookes (2007), Gutierrez and Kelley (2008), and Tetlock, Saar-Tsechansky, and Macskassy (2008). Of these papers, Chan (2003) and Gutierrez and Kelley (2008) are most closely related to this study. The first result in this paper extends the monthly and weekly

findings in Chan (2003) and Gutierrez and Kelley (2008) to daily return reversals around public news. This is not trivial because the correlations between daily returns on news days and weekly and monthly returns surrounding public news are only 0.560 and 0.299, respectively. Interestingly, these correlations are 0.618 and 0.350 on news days with positive abnormal turnover, but just 0.321 and 0.120 on other news days. Neither Chan (2003) nor Gutierrez and Kelley (2008) explores this link between trading activity and returns on news days. By contrast, I analyze whether news predicts changes in volume-induced return momentum, the correlation between absolute returns and volume, and price impact.

This study differs from Stickel and Verrecchia (1994), Pritamani and Singal (2001), Vega (2006), Tetlock et al. (2008), and Tetlock (2009) because it compares high-frequency return reversals on news and non-news days. All of these earlier studies analyze reversals and momentum solely on news days, and the first three look at only earnings news.3 This study’s evidence on return predictability complements the evidence in Chae (2005) and Chava and Tookes (2007), which both mainly analyze trading volume around news events. This study differs from Tetlock et al. (2008) and Tetlock (2009) in its comparison of news and non-news events and its use of news data on the entire cross-section of publicly traded firms.

A third related literature examines intra-day responses to public information—e.g., Lee, Mucklow, and Ready (1993), Fleming and Remolona (1999), Green (2004), and Pasquariello and Vega (2007). The empirical focus of this paper on daily expected returns, correlations between returns and volume, and price impacts differs from the microstructure emphasis on intra-day spreads and depths. A key reason is that, although the news events in this sample have precise time stamps, these time stamps often do not correspond to the intra-day timing of the release of the underlying

3 Stickel and Verrecchia (1994) show that post-earnings announcement drift (PEAD) increases with announcement-day trading volume. Vega (2006) shows that PEAD is higher for firms with low measures of PIN, differences of opinion on public news days, and low media coverage. Tetlock et al. (2008) shows that the words in public news releases predict firms’ future cash flows and their stock returns, albeit briefly. Tetlock (2009) finds that news-day return reversal is higher when prior news, high return volatility, or high liquidity precedes the news day.

information event. Thus, I focus on daily market reactions to news because news usually occurs on the same day as the information event. A benefit of testing the daily expected return predictions of microstructure theory is that these predictions receive less attention in the recent empirical literature on public information events.

Although this paper adopts an identification strategy based on a rational market microstructure model, one could frame many of the empirical results as tests of behavioral asset pricing theories. The two classes of models are not mutually exclusive because specific behavioral biases could motivate the “liquidity” trading in microstructure models. For example, one could relate the results here on return reversals, volume-induced momentum, and the correlation between absolute returns and volume to predictions in the Barberis, Shleifer, and Vishny (1998), Daniel, Hirshleifer, and Subrahmanyam (1998), or Hong and Stein (1999) over- and underreaction models. This behavioral interpretation, however, does not seem necessary because the rational paradigm appears to explain the data and because none of the four news effects is significantly stronger in stocks with low institutional ownership.

I now provide a brief overview of the paper. In Section I, I introduce a simple model of how news resolves information asymmetries that makes four empirical predictions. In Section II, I describe the key empirical measures and present several summary statistics. In Section III, I use regressions to estimate return reversal and volume-induced reversal on news days and non-news days. I present the correlations between absolute returns and volume and the price impact results in Section IV. I provide a concluding discussion of the results in Section V.

I. A Stylized Model in Which Public News Resolves Information Asymmetry

The model here inherits its key economic features from Wang (1994) and LMSW (2002), but makes additional assumptions about the role and timing of public news stories. The model features

three trading periods, two groups of investors, one risky asset, and one risk-free asset. As in Wang

(1994), one investor group (i ) has a temporary informational advantage, but also incurs a privately

observed liquidity or endowment shock. This group combines the traditional roles of informed

traders and liquidity traders, who introduce noise. The other investor group (u ) is relatively

uninformed, but is also rational. Each group is comprised of many investors who behave

competitively as price takers. All investors have constant absolute risk aversion (CARA) utility

functions defined over consumption in period 3, after the risky asset’s liquidating dividend occurs.

The CARA assumption implies that investors’ asset demands do not depend on their wealth.

In periods 0, 1, and 2, both investor groups myopically choose how much to invest in the

risky and risk-free assets. In period 3, they consume their wealth, which depends on the risky asset’s

liquidating dividend. The myopia assumption increases tractability, but does not affect the model’s

qualitative predictions. For simplicity, the risk-free asset pays a zero rate of return and there is no

time discounting. The risky asset supply is normalized to one unit; the supply of the risk-free asset is

perfectly elastic; and both investors’ have risk aversion equal to one.

The informed investors receive a signal in period 1 (s 1) about the firm’s liquidating dividend

() that occurs in time 3, where d is a constant. The signal is normally

distributed according to . Each of the three random components of the dividend is

independently normally distributed according to 32113e e e s d d ++++=1s ),0(s V N ~),0(e t V N e ~and is revealed publicly in period t ,

where t = 1, 2, or 3. In period 2, a public news announcement reveals the signal (s 1) to the

uninformed investors.

In period 1, the informed investors incur a persistent liquidity shock to their endowments of

stock holdings equal to per investor, which is normally distributed according to .

Importantly, this shock persists until after period 2, when the news occurs. Although the uninformed

investors do not observe this liquidity shock, they make rational inferences about its value based on

1n ),0(1n V N n ~

the observed market price in period (p 1) and the initially private signal (s 1) that becomes public in

period 2. A natural interpretation of the model is that the uninformed investors are risk-averse market

makers, who act competitively and rationally.

The timeline below summarizes the key events in the model:

One can compute the equilibrium using standard backward induction techniques. Denote

investors’ demand functions in period t by x it and x ut . From the myopic CARA assumption, informed

demand per investor, excluding the liquidity shock, is:

)

()(11++?=t it t t it it p Var p p E x where the subscripts denote investor group i ’s conditional expectations based on information

available at time t . Demand for each investor in the uninformed group is the same, except the i

subscripts are u subscripts. To obtain the two group demands, one multiplies the individual investor

demands by the total group sizes, which are m for the informed and (1 – m ) for the uninformed.

it By setting demand equal to supply in period 2, I solve for the equilibrium market price:

11212n mV s e e V d p e e ++++?=

The news release allows investors to perfectly infer the value of the private liquidity shock (n 1),

making it effectively publicly observable. As in the Campbell, Grossman, and Wang (1993) model, a

publicly observable liquidity shock has a temporary impact on the stock price.

I look for an equilibrium in period 1 in which p 1 is linear in s 1 and n 1:

1111n b s b e a p n s +++=

where the equilibrium values of the signal and liquidity shock coefficients (b s amd b n ) will be

determined below. Anticipating the linear form of the pricing function, the uninformed investors use

the observed price to learn about s 1 and n 1. Applying the market clearing condition in period 1,

solving for the equilibrium price, and matching the three pricing coefficients on the constant, signal,

and liquidity shock terms yields the solutions:

()()1)1(1)1(21),,,(0222<++++++=

e e n e s n e e n e s e n s s V V m V V mV V V V m m V V mV V V V V m b ()()e n

e e n e s n e e n e s e e n s n e mV V V m V V mV V V V m m V V mV V V m V V V m b mV 2)1(1)1(21)1(),,,(222<+++++++=< ()n

e e n e s s n e e V V m V V mV V V V V m V d a 222)1(1)1(2+++???= Applying the market clearing condition in period 0, when there is symmetric information and no

liquidity shocks have occurred, the initial price is:

)

(3220n n s s e V b V b V d p +??=One can use the pricing and demand equations above to compute abnormal returns and volume in

periods 1 and 2. The period 2 abnormal return (r 2) is the unexpected difference in prices:

21112122)),,,(()),,,(1())((e n V V V m b mV s V V V m b p p E p p E r e n s n e e n s s +?+?=???=

Similarly, the period 3 abnormal return (r 3) is:

1323233))((n mV e p p E p p E r e ?=???=

To compare firms in the news to those out of the news, I analyze the model’s comparative

statics with respect to V s in the parameter region where V s approaches zero. This region is appropriate

for analyzing the impact of a single daily news story that represents a small fraction of a firm’s total

return variance. I also verify in simulations that the theoretical results below hold for larger changes

in V s . Because increasing V s holding the other parameters fixed increases the firm’s total return

variance, I conduct further simulations in which reductions in V e exactly offset the effect of

increasing V s on return variance. None of the comparative statics below change in this specification.

The model’s first two empirical predictions focus on expected post-news returns (r 3). Using

the return equations for r 2 and r 3 above, we compute the return predictability coefficient: 0)),,,(()),,,(1()),,,(()()

(222,3>?++??=n e e n s n e s e n s s n e e n s n e V mV V V V m b V V V V V m b V mV V V V m b mV r Var r r Cov (1)

The derivative of this expression with respect to V s is positive at V s = 0, as Proposition 1 states:

Proposition 1: The regression coefficient of post-news (r 3) returns on news-event returns (r 2)

increases with the informativeness of news (V s ).

The reason is that news, by resolving information asymmetry in period 2, induces the uninformed

investors to partially accommodate the (period-1) liquidity shock from informed investors. In period

3, the remainder of the liquidity shock dissipates. The gradual accommodation of the same (period-1)

liquidity shock in periods 2 and 3 is what causes the positive covariance in returns in periods 2 and 3.

Empirically, I compare return autocorrelations for firms with and without news on the same day.

The model’s second and third empirical predictions are based on the fact that trading volume

in the news period increases with the informativeness of news (V s ). I compute the abnormal trading

volume in period 2 (T 2) as the absolute value of the unexpected change in the informed investor

group’s holdings between periods 1 and 2: 1112122)],,,(2[)],,,(1[))((n V V V m b mV s V V V m b V m x x E x x m T e n s n e e n s s e i i i i ?+?=???=(2)

This equation shows that trading volume follows a folded normal distribution, where the variance of

the underlying normal is proportional to .

n e n s n e s e n s s V V V V m b mV V V V V m b 22)],,,(2[)],,,(1[?+?

Using the standard expression for the expectation of a folded normal variable, one can show that the

derivative of expected abnormal trading volume with respect to news informativeness (V s ) evaluated

at V s = 0 is strictly positive, as Proposition 2 states.

Proposition 2: Expected trading volume (T 2) increases with the informativeness of news (V s ).

Empirically, news is often a binary (0 or 1) variable that is only positively correlated with the

underlying informativeness of news (V s ). Proposition 2 suggests that the extent of trading volume is a

complementary proxy for V s , identifying news days that coincide with more resolution of asymmetric

information and more absorption of the liquidity shock. Thus, the model’s second prediction is that

the return predictability coefficient in equation (1) and Proposition 1 increases with the amount

trading volume on a news day.

A second implication of the trading volume equation is that the correlation between volume

and the absolute value of returns in the news-event period increases with the informativeness of

news. The correlation between absolute returns and volume is given by:

)2/()2)arccos(2))(sin(arccos 2(|)|,(22????+?=πρπρρρr T Corr

where ))),(((21212r x x E x x m Corr i i i i ???=ρ

The correlation unambiguously increases with news informativeness at 0=s V : 02)arccos(2|)|,(22>???=??s s dV d ρV r T Corr ππρ (3)

Both terms in equation (3) are negative at V s = 0, implying that their product is positive.

Proposition 3: The correlation between trading volume and absolute returns in the news-event period

increases with news informativeness (V s ).

The intuition is that news simultaneously reveals informed traders’ signal (s 1) and the value

of the persistent liquidity shock (n 1) to previously uninformed investors. If they learn that the shock

is negative (positive), then future expected returns will be higher (lower) than expected, motivating

uninformed investors to partially accommodate the shock. That is, the revelation of the signal

through news facilitates the absorption of the liquidity shock. More unexpected news leads to both

larger price changes and increased accommodation of the liquidity shock at the time of the news.

Lastly, I examine the price impact of informed trading, which is defined as the regression

coefficient of returns on informed order flows. In the news period, price impact is: n n e s s n e n n e s s e i i i i i i i i V b mV V b V mV b b mV V b m V x x E x x Var x x E x x r Cov 222121212122)2()1())(2()1())(())(,(?+???+????????=?????? (4)

The first term in the expression above shows that the impact of increasing the variance of the signal

(V s ) is to reduce price impact in period 2, as stated in Proposition 4:

Proposition 4: Price impact in the news-event period decreases with news informativeness (V s ).

To see the intuition, suppose that there will be important news released in period 2. Before

this news is released, in period 1, informed traders face a high cost of meeting their liquidity needs,

leading them to trade more on information and less on liquidity. When the news arrives, however,

informed traders will unwind their information-based trades and trade solely for liquidity reasons,

making their price impact appear low. Thus, the fourth prediction of the model is that the price

impact of informed trading decreases as news resolves asymmetric information. Empirically, I use

the Lee and Ready (1991) algorithm for signing order flow to identify informed trades. This

identification approach is valid if the informed group trades more aggressively than the uninformed

group, who effectively act as market makers in this model.

II. Data Description

The primary data source is the Dow Jones (DJ) news archive, which contains all DJ News Service and all Wall Street Journal (WSJ) stories from 1979 to 2007. For each news story in the archive, there are often multiple newswire messages corresponding to separate paragraphs that DJ releases individually. I use the DJ firm code identifier at the beginning of each newswire to assess whether a story mentions a publicly traded US firm. Unfortunately, my manual review of the news stories prior to November 1996 reveals that stories without any firm codes sometimes mention US firms—i.e., the DJ firm codes contain measurement error. More seriously, DJ may back-fill firm codes prior to November 1996 in a systematic fashion that introduces survivorship bias in the data. This survivorship bias does not seem to affect stories after November 1996. Between 95% and 99% of sample firms have news coverage in each year after 1996.

Subperiod analyses—most of which appear in the tables that follow—show that all the main results hold before and after 1996. Using other subperiod cutoffs does not affect these findings. In general, the results are either similar or somewhat stronger in the 1997 to 2007 period, which is not subject to survivorship bias. The fact that survivorship bias does not strengthen the results may be attributable to this paper’s focus on high-frequency return, volume, volatility, and news measures, which do not depend heavily on accurate estimates of stocks’ long-run expected returns.

Even so, I explicitly examine the relationship between stocks’ long-run returns and media coverage to gauge the potential impact of the survivorship bias. I am able to replicate the key Fang and Peress (2009) finding that one-month expected returns are lower for stocks with some media coverage. If anything, this effect is slightly larger in the current data set, which suggests that survivorship bias does not materially affect expected returns. This result also mitigates broader

concerns about survivorship bias because one-month returns are more likely than daily or weekly returns to show evidence of survivorship bias.

The main regression tests use data on news, returns, volume, and firm characteristics. The measure of firm-specific news coverage is an indicator variable (News it = 0 or 1) that is equal to one if firm i’s DJ code appears in any stories in the archive between the close of trading day t – 1 and the close of trading day t. I match the DJ firm codes to US ticker symbols in CRSP by trading date. I match each firm’s news and returns data to accounting (CompuStat), analyst forecast (IBES), institutional holdings (Thomson 13f), and stock transaction data (TAQ).

The analysis below focuses on economically important firms with reliably measured trading returns. The sample includes only stocks with positive trading volume on all days from t – 60 to t – 1, and stocks with prices that exceed $5 on day t – 1. These requirements eliminate many small and illiquid firms, most of which have very few news stories anyway. The sample includes only US firms with common equity (share codes 10 or 11 in CRSP) listed on the NYSE, NASDAQ, or Amex exchange. After imposing these requirements, 13,842 unique firms appear at some point in the 29-year sample. Of these firms, 9,452 have news stories on at least one trading day. This 68% coverage percentage is considerably higher than coverage in Fang and Peress (2009), but somewhat lower than coverage in Chan (2003). The missing firm codes in the pre-1997 DJ archive appear to account for the discrepancy with Chan (2003).

[Insert Figure 1 here.]

Figure 1 depicts the monthly average of the daily percentage of eligible firms covered in the DJ archive. Between two and five percent of firms appear in the archive on most days in the 1980s, whereas 20% to 35% of firms are mentioned on most days in the post-2000 period. I also compute three long-horizon coverage measures for trading days that meet the sample inclusion criteria: the percentage of firms with at least one news story in the current month; the percentage with news in the most recent 12 months; and the percentage of trading days in the most recent 12 months that a firm

appears in the news for the firm at the 90th percentile. This last measure shows how news coverage evolves for the most widely followed firms. All four coverage measures increase over time, and the yearly coverage measure jumps to over 95% shortly after November of 1996. In 1980, news stories occur on 10% of trading days for the firm in the 90th percentile of coverage, but they occur on 60% of trading days in 2007.

III. The Impact of News on Return Reversals

A. Regression Estimates

In the model in Section I and in several related models, liquidity shocks predict larger return reversals and the release of information predicts smaller return reversals. To evaluate whether public news coincides with liquidity or informational shocks, I examine whether news on day t predicts a larger or smaller reversal of firm i’s day-t excess stock return (Ret it). For simplicity, I define Ret it as the firm’s raw day-t return minus the value-weighted market return. The dependent variable is the firm’s ten-day raw return from trading day t+2 through day t+10 (Ret i,t+2,t+10), where I omit day t+1 to mitigate bid-ask bounce. The ten-day horizon matches earlier papers, such as Tetlock et al. (2008), that explore return momentum around news. The results are very similar with a five-day horizon. I define Ret i,t+2,t+10 using raw returns for ease of interpretation. The results below are not sensitive to the specific risk benchmarks chosen because the regressions include controls for several firm characteristics and because short-horizon return predictability is often robust to benchmark selection (Fama (1998)).

The controls for firm characteristics that predict expected returns include monthly measures of firm size (Size it), book-to-market (BM it) ratio, yearly return momentum excluding the most recent calendar month (Mom it), and average daily return volatility during the previous calendar month (TVol it) using standard techniques. I define the size and book-to-market variables as in Fama and

French (1992), the momentum variable as in Jegadeesh and Titman (1993), and the total volatility variable as in Ang, Hodrick, Xing, and Zhang (2006).4 Most regression specifications include abnormal turnover (Turn it) to control for the high volume return premium of Gervais, Kaniel, and Mingelgrin (2001). For consistency, I use the same turnover variable in the interaction terms below that measure volume-induced reversal. Thus, I use the abnormal turnover definition from Campbell, Grossman, and Wang (1993): the log of daily turnover (share volume over shares outstanding), detrended using a rolling 60-day average of log turnover.

In all regressions, the set of independent variables includes the news indicator (News it) and an interaction between news and day-t excess returns (news it*Ret it). Because news coverage is strongly related to firm size (e.g., Chan (2003), Vega (2006), Engelberg (2008), and Fang and Peress (2009)), I include an additional variable (size it*Ret it) to control for possible interactions between size and reversals. To reduce multicollinearity with the size interaction (Size it*Ret it), I demean News it by size quintile on each day t before computing the news interaction term (news it*Ret it).5 I also demean Size it by the mean size for all firms in the sample on each day t before computing the size interaction term (size it*Ret it). Lowercase letters denote the demeaned news and size variables. Throughout this paper, I demean all independent variables before computing interaction terms. The only exceptions are abnormal turnover and excess returns, which both already have means approximately equal to zero by construction.

The regression includes an interaction term to control for volume-induced momentum (Turn it*Ret it) because news and volume are correlated. It also includes an interaction term between news and turnover (news it*Turn it) as a control, in case the high volume return premium depends on the occurrence of news. I also include a triple interaction term (news it*Turn it*Ret it) to assess whether

4 To reduce positive skewness, I compute the logarithms of the size, book-to-market, momentum, and volatility variables. I add constants (k) before computing the log of each variable (x) so that the slope of ln(k+x) is equal to one when x is evaluated at the variable’s unconditional sample mean. This does not affect the results.

5 The regression results based on the raw news variable are qualitatively similar.

volume-induced return reversal depends on news. This coefficient estimate is the basis for testing two auxiliary predictions of the theory that news resolves asymmetric information: first, volume-induced return reversals (momentum) will be lower (higher) on days with news; and second, the impact of news on volume-induced return reversals will be larger for stocks with higher information asymmetry. The complete regression specification is:

Ret i,t+2,t+10 = a + b1 * Ret it + b2 * news it*Ret it+ b3 * Turn it*Ret it+ b4 * news it*Turn it*Ret it

+ c * Controls it + e it for all i on each day t(5) where Controls it = [News it size it*Ret it news it*Turn it Turn it Size it BM it Mom it TVol it]T is an 8 by 1 column vector and c is a 1 by 8 row vector of coefficients. The news-related reversal and news-related volume-induced reversal coefficients (b2 and b4) are the focus of this section.

In the spirit of the Fama and MacBeth (1973) method for estimating expected returns, I estimate equation (5) daily using the cross-section of all firms on each day. Using data from all days increases the efficiency of the regression estimates relative to throwing away data (e.g., Hansen and Hodrick (1980)), which would be necessary if I used weekly or biweekly regressions. I compute the full sample coefficient estimate as the time series average of the daily cross-sectional regression coefficients.6 Using an unweighted average disregards the standard error of each daily coefficient estimate, which is generally inefficient. Instead, I weight each daily coefficient estimate using the inverse of the variance of the daily coefficient as suggested in Ferson and Harvey (1999).7 Because consecutive daily estimates are based on return observations with overlapping nine-day time horizons, the daily estimates of the cross-sectional regression coefficients are positively autocorrelated. Thus, I compute Newey-West (1987) standard errors that are robust to autocorrelation

6 I ignore monthly estimates from months with fewer than 100 firm-days with news stories. This criterion binds only when I divide the sample by firm size, liquidity, analyst coverage, and other characteristics.

7 Even though the standard error of each daily coefficient is biased downward, using the standard errors as weights does not induce a bias in the weighted average if the downward bias is proportional. The reason is that the average weighting cancels in the numerator and denominator of the weighted average.

up to 10 daily lags and heteroskedasticity in the daily coefficient estimates. Using additional lags has no material impact on the inferences.

[Insert Table 1 here.]

Table 1 reports coefficient estimates for all variables in equation (5). The first key result is that the coefficient on the news interaction term (news it*Ret it) is positive, statistically significant, and economically significant. Reversals on days [2,10] of returns on day 0 are 4.2% lower when news occurs on day 0. By contrast, the size of the average reversal—represented by the coefficient on

Ret it—is 9.8% of the day 0 return. Using the coefficients on Ret it, news it*Ret it, news it*Turn it*Ret it , and Turn it*Ret it, along with the average values of news it , news it*Turn it , and Turn it on news days and non-news days, the reversal on news and non-news days are equal to -6.4% and -10.2% of the daily return, respectively. This implies that the reversal of day 0 returns is 38% lower if news occurs on day 0. One can also compare the reversal sizes in basis points rather than percentages of daily returns. The standard deviation of returns on news days is 3.85%, whereas the standard deviation on non-news days is 2.75%. Multiplying these standard deviations by the percentage reversals above, one sees that the news-day return reversal of 39 bps is over 31% lower than the non-news-day reversal of 56 bps. The observed difference of 17 bps in the news and non-news return reversal understates the importance of public information arrival if the news indicator variable is a noisy proxy for public information. The results in subsequent tests that allow reversal to depend on public news characteristics support this view.

The second main result in Table 1 is that the regression coefficient on the news it*Turn it*Ret it variable is consistently positive, statistically significant, and economically significant. The fourth row in Table 1 shows five regression specifications that differ in whether they exclude earnings or non-earnings news and in which period they cover. The robustness in the news it*Turn it*Ret it coefficients indicates that neither earnings news nor survivorship bias drives the results. To gauge the economic impact of news on volume-induced momentum, consider an increase in turnover from the

10th to the 90th percentile of its distribution conditional on news. This increase in turnover leads to a 3.2% increase in momentum of daily returns on news days, but only a 0.5% increase in momentum of daily returns on non-news days. These percentages correspond to volume-induced momentum magnitudes of 19 bps and 3 bps over days [2,10] for news and non-news days, respectively. Together, the first and second key results imply that the average news story reduces return reversal, and that high-volume news stories reduce return reversal by an even larger amount.

[Insert Figure 2 here.]

To summarize these first two results, Figure 2 shows stylized calculations of the predicted percentage of a stock’s daily return that is reversed in four situations: when news occurs (news it = 0.702) or does not occur (news it = -0.099), and when turnover conditional on news is high (90th percentile) or low (10th percentile). The four sets of bars in Figure 2 represent the predicted return reversal for all four combinations of news and non-news, and high and low turnover. The dark gray, light gray, and black bars show how these reversals change when the sample includes all news, excludes earnings news, and excludes non-earnings news.

Figure 2 provides a simple graphic interpretation of the first two empirical results. The fact that the first two sets of bars in Figure 2 are statistically and economically significantly lower than the second two sets of bars implies that news reduces return reversal on average. The second main result is that the difference between the third and fourth set of bars in Figure 2 is much larger than the difference between the first two sets of bars. This means that volume reduces return reversal, but only when it accompanies news. Equivalently, one could say that public news reduces return reversal by more when it accompanies high volume.

The numerous subsample results in Table 1 and Figure 2 demonstrate that the impacts of news on reversal and volume-induced momentum are both quite robust. For example, columns four and five in Table 1 show that the impact of news on reversals (news it*Ret it coefficient) and volume-induced momentum (news it*Turn it*Ret it coefficient) remains similar regardless of the period. This is

新闻策划书大全

新闻策划书大全 新闻报道的特点是:真实、新鲜、及时、重要、趣味可读,时效性极强。一般读新闻报道的习惯是:通篇浏览标题,优中选优,不留死角,仔细阅读。1、自主性:新闻界自主选择报道或者揭露目标,自主进行调查活动。下面,小编给大家介绍一下关于 新闻报道策划书篇(一) 一、策划书名称尽可能具体的写出策划名称,如“年月日信息系活动策划书”,置于页面中央。 二、活动背景: 这部分内容应根据策划书的特点在以下项目中选取内容重点阐述;具体项目有:基本情况简介、主要执行对象、近期状况、组织部门、活动开展原因、社会影响、以及相关目的动机。其次应说明问题的环境特征,主要考虑环境的内在优势、弱点、机会及威胁等因素,对其作好全面的分析(SWOT分析),将内容重点放在环境分析的各项因素上,对过去现在的情况进行详细的描述,并通过对情况的预测制定计划。如环境不明,则应该通过调查研究等方式进行分析加以补充。

三、活动目的及意义: 活动的目的、意义应用简洁明了的语言将目的要点表述清楚;在陈述目的要点时,该活动的核心构成或策划的独到之处及由此产生的意义都应该明确写出。 四、活动名称: 根据活动的具体内容影响及意义拟定能够全面概括活动的名称。 五、活动目标: 此部分需明示要实现的目标及重点(目标选择需要满足重要性、可行性、时效性)。 六、活动开展: 作为策划的正文部分,表现方式要简洁明了,使人容易理解。在此部分中,不仅仅局限于用文字表述,也可适当加入统计图表等;对策划的各工作项目,应按照时间的先后顺序排列,绘制实施时间表有助于方案核查。另外,人员的组织配置、活动对象、相应权责及时间地点也应在这部分加以说明,执行的应变程序也应该在这部分加以考虑。 七、经费预算: 活动的各项费用在根据实际情况进行具体、周密的计算后,用清晰明了的形式列出。 八、活动中应注意的问题及细节: 内外环境的变化,不可避免的会给方案的执行带来一些不确定 是多少,造成的损失多大等也应在策划中加以说明。

杭州市年12月九年级语文月考试题及答案新人教版

2017学年九年级12月质量检测 语文试题卷 满分120分,考试时间120分钟。 一(30分) 1.下面语段中加点字的注音全都正确的一项是() 冬天的北方寒风凛冽,大雪肆虐,一出门,我蓦地打了个寒颤,心想:“这时候,若能在温暖的屋子里,该是多么惬意啊!”只有红梅,不惧严寒,开放出殷红的花朵,在风雪中傲然挺立。 A.mòchàn xiàyān B. mùzhàn qièyīn C.mòzhàn qièyān D. mùzhàn xiàyīn 2. 下列句子中没有错别字的一项是()(3分) A.在职业生涯的第20个赛季,洛杉矶湖人队科比?布莱恩特正式宣布他将在本赛季结束后退役,这引发了微信朋友圈持续的刷屏感慨。 B. 党中央明确国家安全战略方针和总体布署,推动国家安全工作取得显著成效。 C. 西湖秀美的风景妇儒皆知,一到周末,在杭城读书的大学生常常邀上挚友前往西湖游玩。D.“不就是等一场久违的雪吗?简直就是小提大作!”穿丝袜的摩登女笑得得意的背后藏着更多的是阴险。世界迎合了她魅惑的性感,把她水性杨花的个性表现得淋漓尽致。 3.下列句子中加点的词语使用恰当的一项是( )(3分) A.王家卫导演的电影《一代宗师》虽然失意奥斯卡最佳外语片,但获得了奥斯卡最佳摄影和最佳服装设计两项题名。 B.就算追溯到天涯海角,中国政府也要将逍遥海外的贪污分子绳之以法。 C.央视春晚上,蔡明将一个退休老人的形象演得绘声绘色,博得了大家的一致好评。 D.西湖边草长莺飞,春色宜人,各地的游客纷至沓来,来领略秀美的湖光山色。 4.下列各句中,没有语病的一句是()(3分) A.武亦姝在最后一场比赛中,与陈更、李宜幸、张淼淼强强PK,以317分获得攻擂,最后战胜彭敏,成为冠军。 B.戛纳电影节将于2017年5月在杭州举办MIPCHINA国际影视内容高峰论坛,这是戛纳电视节品牌活动首次登陆中国。 C.网络之所以让那么多的网友着迷的重要原因,是因为他们下单后输入账号密码时基本没有感觉到是在花钱。 D.杭州举办2022年第19届亚运会,将推动奥林匹克运动的发展,同时将加强杭州的国际知名度,促进杭州经济、社会的全面发展。

电视节目策划书范文学习资料

电视节目策划书范文 以下电视节目策划书范文由提供,更多策划书范文,尽在2、“物化”梦想: 知名企业提供的高端管理职位:高级别还有辅助性的职业加速奖金或礼包。所有一切具备足够的梦想特征,足够的诱-惑力。 3、人才群: 由10名求职者组成,他们经过企业和节目制作方的双重标准选择,首先有很好的职业素养及良好的形象及交际能力,同时具备高差异化的生活学习背景、性格及表现张力。 4、亲友评估团: 由10名求职者的直系亲属组成,他们在淘汰环节中可以通过投票赦免一人。在职场的比拼中,由于关系到每个选手的生存命运,所以除了他们自己之外,他们的直系亲属应该是最为“挂心”的成员,节目引入这个特殊的群体参与左右他们命运的走向,使人物关系更加丰富,戏剧冲突更具悬念,在职场冷冰冰的竞争中多了一条感性的情绪线索。 5、商业案例: 《绝对挑战》中选择的测试案例都是现代商业社会中最重要的最不可或缺的方向,而且也是我们在职场中最常用最实际的环节,如市场推广、营销、团队管理、项目开拓、公益活动等等,而且任务都经过了市场专家的再次设计和升级,

具有很好的观赏性和戏剧冲突基础,而且也能准确的考核出职场人的基本素质二来以一些较低的职场事端和技巧降低收视门槛,进而使观众有所收获。 6、丰富的职场平台: 虽然我们是以一家公司为基本合作平台,但同时我们会和不同的商业机构形成联动,如每级根据不同的任务,会和高级的广告公司、拍卖机构、剧组、酒店等等合作,以期为选手搭建一个平常无法获取的高级商业平台,形成实现职业梦想的路径通道,同时,与这些高级商业平台的合作,不但增加了节目的品质,也满足了观众的心理欲望。 7、故事和情绪: “因为故事而开始关心人的命运”是电视剧的收视拉力,在特别节目中,无论是智商情商的搏杀,还是淘汰和获胜,在整个竞争的过程中,故事性和心理活动及情绪的捕捉是节目中最着重表达的地方,一个真实的职场环境必然带来真实的感受,我们力求将这种行为和行为背后的心理动因准确传递出来,必将引起对味位共鸣,这也是生活写实类“真人秀”的核心。 范文二 一、背景分析:当下,娱乐文化已经被提高到了一个前所未有的地位,也成为我们这个时代大众消费的主要精神产品。单调的戏曲节目,已不能再吸引大众的眼球。

新闻专题策划书模板

新闻专题策划模板 例1。“海大火灾门”新闻专题策划书 一、选题分析: 1、题材分析:海大学生宿舍发生火灾属于重大突发性事件,报道具有时效性、接近性。对其报道动作要迅速,以最快的速度把现场的情况传达给受众。为受众传达最新最全的消息。 2、角度分析:在报道这次火灾事件时,媒体工作者要客观、全面,不要成为某一方的代言人,其中包括学生、受害者、相关领导干部、官方代表。在报道中,要体现人文关怀。通过对事件的跟踪报道,反思高校学生用电与学校限电的矛盾,捉住事件新动态来突破揭示事件的本质。 3、深度分析:这一类的高校火灾事件并不少见,为什么会屡屡见于报道。背后透漏的是什么是高校管理工作的不善与失败高校学生的安全隐患到底有多大……我们设置本专题的目的不是报道海大的这次火灾本身,希望透过这次报道,引起相关部门的重视。各高校应该引以为鉴,对存在于校园中的各种安全隐患要有一套完整的解决方案。更重要的是要在事件发生之前做好防备工作。

二、内容分析:本专题暂分为6个部分。 最新报道:采用追踪连续报道,以时间为维度将事件的发生、发展过程、当前状态、未来趋向以短消息或通讯形式展示。在首页,每条消息以标题的形式展示。 事件细节:以文本的形式把事件发生的时间、地点、人物、原因、发生了什么等新闻要素显示在专题首页,方便读者对事件的了解。新闻图集:把与此事件有关的具有新闻性的图片以幻灯片的形式展示在专题首页。 视频报道:放置海大媒体对这个事件的视频报道。 类似事件:以高校为维度,将类似的新闻突发事件有选择性的放在专题首页。以图片加核心提示的形式链接下一级的新闻。 高校领导态度:收集一些针对发生火灾这一事件,一些学校领导做出的回应,发表的意见和做出的决策。还可以包括相关教育部门的态度和应对方案。 讨论区:讨论区分两部分,一个是‘评论’专栏,一个是‘灌水区’。‘评论’可以链接到与此事件相关的博客、评论文章等,‘灌水区’是浏览此专题的人留下的言论。讨论区为受众提供的一个发表言论的平台,以意见态度为维度,受众可以对当事人的态度、相关领导部门的意见、社会反映等提出自己的看法、建议等。

电视节目策划书范文

新闻节目策划书范文 一、栏目类型:新闻类报道 二、栏目名称:《一周播报》 三、栏目宗旨 整理一周来校园内发生的事情以及国内外的重大事件,对这些消息进行回顾和某一程度上的深度报道。宣传学院领导以及各系领导和老师的最新工作动态, 关注同学们的学习生活状态,整顿学风,提高同学们的思想觉悟,活跃校园氛围,建立良好的舆论监督制度,争创和谐校园。 四、栏目定位及受众分析 1、主要以报道北院的活动为主。因为距离、交通等因素,再加上校园电视 台刚成立不久,我们没有更多的能力兼顾南北两院,所以主要以报道北院的活动为主。在此基础上再报道发生在南院的具有重大意义的事件。 2、主要以报道校园新闻为主。包括院党委、团委、学生会、学社联、各学 生社团以及各系部举办的各项活动,教研组举办的各项专业汇报等活动,在同学中有良好形象或对同学们产生深刻影响的个人、组织或事件。其次报道国内外重大时事政治、经济、文化、社会等新闻。 3、受众包括学院领导以及广大师生。作为新闻栏目很有必要成为领导、老 师与同学们之间的桥梁,每期节目尽量做到多视角、多方位的报道。 五、栏目风格及内容 1、栏目风格 (1)整体风格:正式、严肃,又不乏人文关怀。 (2)主持人风格:富有清新、自然、亲切、学生气质。 (3)串联词风格:栏目分版块进行,版块之间分工明确。串联词根据这些 版块来组织语言,要求语言正式、通俗易懂。 2、栏目内容及要求 分版块进行,具体如下:

(1)艺苑新闻。这一版块在栏目中所占时长为二分之一至三分之二。内容 包括院党委、团委、学生会、学社联、各学生社团以及各系部举办的各项活动, 教研组举办的各项专业汇报等活动,在同学中有良好形象或对同学们产生深刻影 响的个人、组织或事件。提倡内容积极向上,能有良好的带动作用。要求新闻通 俗易懂,在传播了基本的信息之后根据新闻的具体情况进行某一程度上的深度报 道;每一期的新闻能够全面的站在不同身份、视角去报道,做到雅俗共赏。 (2)艺苑视角。这一版块作为新闻特写出现,充分体现本栏目的人文关怀。主要报道在同学中有良好形象或对同学们产生深刻影响的个人或组织,宣传积极向上的精神,在广大学生中起到模范带头作用。要求被报道对象是在同期节目新闻中出现,并取得优异成绩的个人或组织。这一版块最重要的一点是一定要贴近广大师生,对于学生这一受众群体来说,这也是本节目得到肯定的关键。 (3)其他新闻。以简讯的形式出现。考虑到实际情况,素材的来源主要以 网上下载的视频和图片为主,然后配以播音员的解说词。在前期筛选素材时,以跟本校、老师、学生的利益相关的新闻优先。 A.省内简讯。囊括最近省内发生的重大时事政治、经济、文化、社会等新 闻,从多方位、多角度去搜集新闻。以跟本校、老师、学生的利益相关的新闻为主。 B.国内简讯。囊括最近国内发生的重大时事政治、经济、文化、社会等新 闻,从多方位、多角度去搜集新闻。以建设和谐社会、增强民族自豪感的新闻为主。 C.国际简讯。囊括最近国际上发生的重大时事政治、经济、文化、社会等 新闻,从多方位、多角度去搜集新闻。 (4)滚动新闻。在每期栏目的下方不间断的播放滚动新闻,包括本期栏目 的新闻回放以及新闻预告,参与或目睹新闻事件的人物对事件的认识、感受。 六、工作人员的设置与要求 1、播音员两名。一男一女。具体要求如下: (1)不断加强业务学习, 提高播音水平, 走采编播相结合复合型主持人的道路。 (2) 调整、保证最佳播音状态, 服装得体、语言流畅。 (3) 严格遵守岗位时间。工作时间内不得擅自离岗。

专题访谈类电视节目策划书

专题访谈类电视节目策划 背景阐述:当前的消费市场中,大学生作为一个特殊的消费群体正受到越来越大的关注。由于大学生年龄较轻,群体较特别,他们有着不同于社会其他消费群体的消费心理和行为。一方面,他 们有着旺盛的消费需求,另一方面,他们尚未获得经济上的独立,消费受到很大的制约。消费观念 的超前和消费实力的滞后,都对他们的消费有很大影响。 特殊群体自然有自己特殊的特点,同时难免存在一些非理性的消费甚至一些消费的问题。 云南网近期也发布发布的一则关于《大学生消费“大起底”》新闻,对在昆的七所高校大学生进行了消费起底调查。针对此现象,深入发掘制作一期访谈节目。 节目宗旨大学生群体较特别,他们有着不同于社会其他消费群体的消费心理和行为。一他们有着旺盛的消费需求,他们尚未获得经济上的独立,消费受到很大的制约,针对云南大学生的消费,节目的宗旨旨在呼吁大学生理性消费。 三、节目定位 大学生及其有关的消费群体 四、节目内容 1、节目名称:《社会大调查》 2、节目形式:访谈节目(与场外调查采访相结合) 3、节目的结构内容: 第一部分:场内演播厅的录制 (1)、现场人员构成: 主持人2 人(室内演播厅主持与室外调查采访主持)、嘉宾(采访消费 情况请入现场的大学生1 人、大学生的家长1 人、 市场消费调查员1 人), 现场观众若干 (2)、演播厅的布置舞台整体环境设置成蓝色的环境,有权威的感觉。 舞台构成观众席和舞台两部分。 观众席围绕舞台,舞台中央是LED显示屏,用于播放视频资料及室 外的调查采访,舞台中主持人和市场调查员坐于舞台左边,采访的 学生及家长坐于舞台右边。 (3)节目的具体构成细分 1.(同步画面:出现电脑或者屏幕关于该新闻的文字拍摄。)

电视新闻专题策划案

大学生自主创业--"开网店"专题 ●背景浅析 当前社会科技发展迅速,随着人类生活节奏的加快和互联网在世界的进一步普及应用,网上购物逐渐成为人们的消费行为之一。正是如此,“开网店”也形成了当今大学生自主创业的一种潮流方式,本次新闻专题主要是探讨关于大学生网络购物风潮的影响和有关网络购物所要注意的问题等。 ●企划动机 网络购物盛行可以说是一种社会现象,也是一个值得重视的社会问题。网络购物究竟给大学生创业者带来了什么方便之处?是什么原因导致大家都愿意在网上创业?学生开网店,也能作为一种社会实践的能力吗?自主网上创业到底是不是所有人都能成功呢?具体在网上开店创业要注意的地方有哪些?还有怎样运用法律的知识来保护自己等。 ●节目设定 节目基本信息: 节目名称<<给力大学生>> 节目类别新闻专题类节目 节目主旨扑捉大学生自主创业潮流中的热点方法,普及关于自主创业的知识。 节目目标这一期是针对网购风潮从而到信息传递和普及网购知识的目的 节目定位主要为大学生打造 节目内容由主持人对于自主大学生网店创业成功的人员采访实例进行引入,然后就这个实例进行对其他学生的一系列采访,明白现在大学生对于开网店创业的一个普遍的认识和了解以及对于别人开网店成功的一些想法。针对这些想法,我们进一部采访这个方面的专家老师,让他给我们体一些建议,解答一些问题。怎样去开一个属于自己的网店;具体类别有哪些;是不是所有人开网店都能成功;有什么成功的经验;开网店会遇到那些困难,比如网络纠纷等怎么去解决,开店纳税怎么解决等。让节目给想网络自主创业的大学生们一个清晰的建议,从而让他们认识到这么一个创业的办法到底适不适合自己,合理地安排自己在大学和大学后期间的创业安排。 剪辑叙事方式是以小见大的发散式叙述方式 节目长度 15-25分钟 节目预算 (略) 工作人员安排: 栏目组织者:华中师范大学武汉传媒学院09编导5班新闻小组 栏目的目标对象:关注网络自主创业的大学生 栏目实施拍摄地点:华师传媒 节目导演方紫嫣 节目策划方紫嫣张伊琦毛静雯 节目主持人刘洁玲 节目记者毛静雯 节目邀请嘉宾自主创业大学生--罗蓓网络政策购物与法规指导老师---王昂(老师) 节目后期制作戴亚佩 其他参加拍摄人员汪清杨泽宇

新闻策划书模板.doc

新闻策划书模板 一、模拟新闻发布会的目的 为了进一步推进管理工程系各专业的实践教学,培养学生综合运用所学知识的能力,丰富学生的第二课堂,加强校园文化建设,在学生学完市场营销、公共关系、推销谈判与技巧、社交礼仪等课程后,由系部带头举办模拟新闻发布会,目的在与激发学生学习的兴趣,掌握查找资料、引用资料的方法,能从相关的报刊、书籍、网站或其他媒体中获取所需要的资料; 培养学生的口语交际能力及谈判能力。 二、新闻发布会的流程 1、确定新闻发布会日期、地点、新闻点等。注意事项:与希望发布事件日期相配合,促进自身对外宣传,挖掘新闻点、制造新闻效应、注意避免与重大新闻事件撞车。该步骤应在正式新闻发布会前20天完成,最迟15天,并在邀请函发布前预定会场,否则会影响下一步工作。 2、确定组织者与参与人员,包括广告公司、领导、客户、同行、媒体记者等,与新闻发布会承办者协调规模与价格,签定合同,拟订详细邀请名单、会议议程、时间表、发布会现场布置方案等。注意事项:该步骤主要由主办者提出要求,承办者具体负责。

3、按照邀请名单,分工合作发送邀请函和请柬,确保重要人员不因自身安排不周而缺席发布会。回收确认信息,制定参会详细名单,以便下一步安排。注意事项:该步骤一定要计划周密,有专人负责,适当放大邀请名单,对重要人物实施公关和追踪,并预备备用方案,确保新闻发布会参与人的数量和质量。 4、购买礼品,选聘主持人、礼仪人员和接待人员,并进行培训和预演。设计背板,布置会场,充分考虑每一个细节,比如音响和放映设备、领导的发言稿、新闻通稿、现场的音乐选择、会议间隙时间的余兴安排等。 5、正式发布会前提前一到两个小时,检查一切准备工作是否就绪,将会议议程精确到分钟,并制定意外情况补救措施。 6、按计划开始发布会。发布会程序通常为来宾签到、贵宾接待、主持人宣布发布会开始和会议议程、按会议议程进行、会后聚餐交流、有特别公关需求的人员的个别活动。 7、监控媒体发布情况,整理发布会音像资料、收集会议剪报,制作发布会成果资料集 一般的大型活动都需要新闻曝光,扩大知名度,这样才会激起更多的连锁反应,这就是为什么在考站大型活动中总是有很多的记者和摄像机到场,这样才能烘托气氛! 但是大型活动的新闻策划确实一项最基本,最重要的事

自创电视节目策划案

《帮帮堂》策划案 策划分析与首期节目策划 策划分析 —、节目概况: 《帮帮堂》是一档全新的生活服务类节目,它主要介绍一些服饰搭配、生活小妙招、创新菜肴做法等生活资讯。《帮帮堂》的最大亮点是将采用类似情景喜剧《爱情公寓》的节目形式,节目的主持人同时也是节目的主要演员,饰演几个刚参加工作的年轻人,他们合租一个名叫"帮帮堂"的公寓。每一期的内容都以这几个年轻人演的情景喜剧的形式播出,也就是说,把每一期要介绍的同一主题的生活资讯编写成喜剧剧本,每一期节目都是一集类似《爱情公寓》的情景喜剧。 二、策划动机: 虽然现在市场上的生活服务类节目不少,但是基本都采用主持人串联节目加上拼盘式信息的形式,缺乏新意,容易导致观众审美疲劳。加之,近来的《爱情公寓》《家有儿女》《武林外传》等几部情景喜剧颇受欢迎,说明轻松娱乐的叙述方式颇为观众所喜爱。从"求同原则" 方面考虑,市场上成功的生活服务类节目不少,说明观众的收视需求大,且生活服务类节目不容易收到政策上的制约;从”求异原则"方面考虑,《帮帮堂》和现有的生活服务类栏目形式完全不同,它更具娱乐性,应该更能迎合年轻观众的收视品味。再者,虽然《帮帮堂》节目内容庞杂,但也因此为剧本创作提供了足够的空间。综上,《帮帮堂》应该能够开拓缝隙市场。 三、调查分析: 现在电视上的生活服务类节目着实不少,特别是限娱令出台以来,许多如《我是大美人》《美丽俏佳人》《女人我最大》等综艺娱乐节目也标榜自己是大型生活服务类节目,由此,《帮帮堂》将来遭遇的竞争之激烈可见一斑。 目前市场上和《帮帮堂》一样,主要介绍生活小妙招、独门做菜秘方、最新生活资讯的节目很多,例如央视的《购物街》《超市大赢家》;旅游卫

电视综艺节目策划范文

电视综艺节目策划范文 电视节目应该聚焦青年,透析青年群体心理,设抓住现代年轻人的心理,解决根本问题。本文是整理的电视综艺节目策划范文,欢迎参阅。 电视综艺节目策划范文1 这是一档倡导聪明+勤奋+勇气=成功的职业理念,鼓励人们用科学的职场视角剖析自己,用积极的态度改变自己职业生涯的职业励志节目。 这是一次最有生命力的真人秀节目尝试,无论从内容到形式依然突出绝对挑战核心理念的节目,其绝对之处体现在精心设计的商场上智商和情商的较量把电视节目的游戏成分淡化了下来,应该算是迄今为止最贴近生活最有生活原型素材的纪实秀。与虚构游戏类真人秀不同,现实的商业特性锻造了更高级别真人秀的节目特性。 这是挑战专业类节目收视率瓶颈的一次积极尝试。统计得知,良好的系列节目中的故事特性和悬念特性能有效的积累收视,将稳定的专业节目收视人群改变为专业加戏剧的收视人群对《绝对挑战》未来的收视环境有非常好的突破作用。 这是一次对节目整合营销的一次有益尝试 一、节目的立足点《绝对挑战》不得不做的改变 1、传承真实,保证收视源动力 《绝对挑战》的职业梦想很高,但绝对真实。它涵

盖的内容最实际:职业机会、地位、金钱、社会认可、精神欲望,所以,当我们强化这个梦想并为这个梦想提供更具含金量机会的时候,没有人会不注目。我们将严格保持原有节目的绝对真实:真实的企业参与,真实的高职位、真实的应聘者、真实的招聘结果,谁会实现这个梦想呢,要实现这样的梦想需要具备什么条件呢?如何通过实际的努力实现这个梦想?这些真实的心理对位构成了最强劲的收视源动力,这是和别的游戏类真人秀最大的不同。 2、强化戏剧表现打破专业类节目的收视平庸现状 《绝对挑战》进入今年,收视大幅攀升,几乎是去年收视分额的两倍,大家的努力为节目赢得了可喜的收视基础。但同时,节目制作水平的日益精良并没有最大限度的弥补节目专业性带来的收视不利,导致收视横向比较平庸。在调查中,我们发现观众更期待在周末看到一个真实的戏剧。《绝对挑战》系列节目更象一部城市幸存者,每一个测试项目中都包括了团队合作,个人贡献,领导才能,压力对抗等等办公室必备的基本因素和戏剧冲突,而复杂的多的人物关系和悬念设置很大程度上迎合了收视特性,情节和情绪成为捕捉的主体。如果职场里表现的可以代表普遍意义的商业的话,那么它就是第一部商业影像日记。节目的最高目标是利用职场平台,描绘实现职业梦想的过程,回答大多数人在职场和人生中都可能面对的问题,核心是职业人的命运。那么,

电视新闻栏目策划方案

《新闻导航》电视栏目策划书 一、现实环境 企划动机:突出电视媒体的服务性和引导性。作为杂志型早间新闻栏目,《新闻导航》立志为大众带去最新、最需要的新闻资讯,让受众在清早刚起床就能与社会做良好的沟通,成为一剂重要的润滑剂;同时传播先进的思想理念,引导受众积极正确的人生观、价值观。 二、栏目设定 1栏目名称:《新闻导航》 2栏目类别:杂志型新闻栏目 3栏目主旨:围绕当前社会大众感兴趣的问题,涉及社会生活的各个方面进行较广泛深报道,揭露表层下的实质问题。 4栏目目标:沟通社会,传递信息 5栏目定位:突出电视媒体的服性和导向性 6栏目内容: a.国内外重大事件 b.民生改革话题,如医疗保险、住房问题 c.影响重大的社会事件 d.平民人物的现实生活及其引发的社会状况 e.文化艺术生活服务资讯 7栏目特色:带领观众关注新闻 8栏目风格:精致,赋予美感,应当做到镜头中节目多于人。片头、片尾和提要:片头可选择《新闻导航》的栏目主持人用轻松的口吻说出栏目宣传语:“新闻导航,关注您的关注。”配上动感和极富节奏感的音乐,增强了节目的时代气息;片尾播放制作团队并可选择播放经典歌曲及热门网络视频;内容提要可选出本期的重点新闻剪辑成片段播出,以引发观众观看兴趣 9主持要求:一男一女主持人搭档,要具备较强的理解能力,驾驭话题、组织讨论的能力,现场应变能力

等多方面的素质 10节目长度:每档40分钟 11播出时段:每天早7:10 — 7: 50(包括4分半钟广告) 12播出次数:每天早7:10 — 7: 50 13工作人员:主持人2名、记者(外景主持)若干、工作人员若干 14 设备场所:a. 演播室 b. 合成制作机房 c. 外景拍摄用的摄像机和拾音话筒2套 15运营要求:拉近观众距离,报道形式灵活多样 a.民生新闻注重用平民视角,用老百姓的语言来报道新闻,摒弃传统新闻的“高高在上,冰冷生硬”报道方式,采用“平视”角度,用通俗易懂的百姓语言来报道新闻,拉近与观众的距离,达到想百姓之所想、急百姓之所急的宣传目的。同时着力突出新闻报道的现场感。在报道过程中,记者善于运用手中的摄像机镜头和话筒来记录现场,通过生动真实的镜头语言和被采访对象朴实感人的百姓语言,让观众产生一种身临其境的感觉,增强新闻的感染力。 b.讲究技巧,精心编排栏目内容。一档精彩的杂志型新闻栏目离不开一线记者的前期采访,而后期编辑的整体编排工作更是起到了画龙点睛的作用。栏目间的编排生动活泼,不同的栏目有不同的特色,不同的栏目有不容的时间长度。保证每个栏目内容新鲜,体裁新颖、有吸引力并能激发观众兴趣。由于节目的内容变化、节目体裁和形式都不同,使整个节目呈现出不同的节奏变化,这种变化符合观众的收拾心里,能够长时间的吸引观众收看节目。 三、栏目的经营创收 1、栏目前期投入预计: 2、栏目广告收入预计: 3、栏目赞助: 4、栏目联办:

新闻报道拍摄策划方案模板

新闻报道拍摄策划方案模板
一、新闻主题(系列报道、专题报道)
1、系列报道:围绕同一新闻题材、新闻主题从不同侧面、不同角度作多次、连续的报 道。不拘泥于事件顺序,但要做到形散神不散,严格围绕新闻主题,以求对新闻事实作比较 系统、全面、深度的报道。(针对不同新闻题材、新闻主题寻找不同角度)
2、专题报道:对某些具有典型意义和较高新闻价值的新闻人物、事件、问题、社会现 象等, 进行记录调查分析解释评述等, 深入系统而又生动反映其发生发展和结果及影响的全 过程,揭示主题的深刻意义。(针对不同新闻题材、新闻主题,进行调查分析,撰写文稿时 要将主题研读通透,文稿应具有一定的评述能力)
二、新闻题材、主题分析 1、系列报道:针对不同的新闻题材、新闻主题,根据拍摄要求,确定系列报道集数, 选定不同的角度、侧面进行新闻题材、新闻主题分析。 2、专题报道:对典型事件或具有高新闻价值的人物题材等进行深度挖掘,调查分析解 释评述,要有理有据不浮夸,并且要分析的生动不古板。
三、基础内容(实地采访前准备工作) 1、项目名称:确定系类报道项目名称; 2、项目核心:将本次系列报道核心观点明确,围绕核心展开报道; 3、数据支持:资料数据佐证,相关人物数据佐证; 4、记者提问:非出镜形式提问,相关人物发表评论看法; 5、旁白撰写:逻辑思维明确的同时,灵活运用,生动,具有吸引力,并具有一定的评 论能力; 6、现场采访:对相关当事人进行现场采访时,撰写采访提纲,临时采访应做记录,方 便后期资料整理。
觞开思维 精诚制作

分类 项目名称 项目核心
内容 确定系类报道项目名称; 将本次系列报道核心观点 明确;
备注 明确主题 围绕核心展开报道
数据支持
资料数据佐证, 相关人物数 据佐证;
数据收集应以客观事实为 依据 布局合理,逻辑思维明确
记者提问
非出镜形式提问, 相关人物 发表评论看法;
旁白撰写
逻辑思维明确的同时, 灵活 运用,生动,具有吸引力
具有一定的论述能力
现场采访
对相关当事人进行现场采 访时,撰写采访提纲
临时采访应做记录, 方便后 期资料整理。
四、工作细分(记者、摄像、编导) 1、预期稿件:由编导通过前期资料收集,撰写概念稿件;(大纲即可) 2、被采访人:在与编导提前沟通的前提下,准备受访内容; 3、采访内容:由编导提前列提纲,无法提前预期的,在受访当天现场列提纲; 4、摄像准备: 与编导沟通拍摄大致流程及拍摄意向, 检查设备 (待机情况, 设备状态) 。
五、拍摄流程(根据不同情况撰写)
觞开思维 精诚制作

《女医明妃传》的经典台词

《女医明妃传》的经典台词 1、你跪在我面前,要把她嫁给你的时候,你说爱她,护她。 2、以后朕不会再让任何人欺负你。 3、没有,我一直都把你当好朋友。 4、所谓医女不过一个名号。 5、我之所以临时登基,也是为了我们大明不落入鞑子之手。 6、执子之手。 7、允贤当着东厂人的面给徐老夫人治病,万一太后知道了,有咱们的好果子吃吗? 8、绝对不要再失去一个大明将士,朕有责任保护你们的生命。 9、我是当今皇上的亲弟弟,现在我要正式向你迎娶令爱,我要封允贤为妃。 10、允贤哪里对不起你了,你要娶王美麟。 11、看清楚这是哪儿。这里是土木堡,不是你的紫禁城! 12、有胆你就把我关死。 13、我是当今皇上的亲弟弟,郕王,朱祁钰。现在我要正式向你迎娶令爱,我要封允贤为我的王妃。 14、我没资格管?我把天下都给你了!你连一个女人都保护不了。 15、执子之手,与子偕老。

16、你明明知道我是女子,不能在腰榆处施针。 17、允贤是我的女人,你没资格管。 18、我是皇帝,也是郑齐,以后朕不会再让任何人欺负你了,你还是可以把我当做郑齐。 19、你是怕朝里的人,知道咱们谈家的真实身份,可是我不 忍心让咱们祖传了上百年的医术断了根。 20、原来那个允氏,就是杭家的活菩萨。 21、我是皇帝,也是郑齐。 22、朕记得,你却不记得了。如今忠在哪里,诚在哪里。 23、你说过爱她、护她,你做到了吗? 24、你告诉朕,你有没有一点喜欢朕? 25、与子偕老。 26、你们个个说朕不配当皇帝,可朕现在就是皇帝,朕是堂 堂正正的皇帝。 27、不是说好了,要共生死的吗? 28、我告诉你,允贤是我的女人,是我的女人!你没资格 管! 29、违令者,斩! 30、大明的将士们,与我杀出城外,救回皇兄!

电视节目创意活动方案模板五篇

电视节目创意活动方案模板五篇 电视栏目层出不穷,电视节目策划才能快速吸引人们的目光呢?撰写策划书就是用现有的知识开发想象力,在可以得到的资源的现实中最可能最快的达到目标。以下是WTT为大家精心准备的电视节目创意活动方案五篇,仅供参考! 电视节目创意活动方案1 一、背景分析: 在电视娱乐节目蓬勃发展的今天,能在令人眼花缭乱的娱乐节目中脱颖而出,能满足观众日益提高的娱乐和审美需求,成为我们应该关注的问题。娱乐节目的泛娱乐化、模式化、低俗化的倾向日趋明显,让娱乐节目良好的践行寓教于乐的宗旨,通过新颖的形式和丰富的节目内容刺激观众的视听神经,满足观众的消遣娱乐需求的同时提升节目的知识性和思想性,这在娱乐节目的策划中显得尤其重要。 电影艺术是一种综合了艺术和科技的兼有时间和空间性质的综合性艺术,它通过在屏幕上创造出直接的感观影像来再现和表现生活。电影自产生以来便因其独特的视听魅力和思想艺术备受人们喜爱,也成为人们娱乐生活的重要组成部分。 电影所展开的故事总让人心向往之,而其中所涉及的知识又是包罗万象,如果能让人身临其境的走进虚幻的电影世界,去亲身解读那些扑朔迷离的人和事,那么这既能满足诸多观影者的心愿,又能挖掘出许多被我们忽略过的知识和思想,既能达成利用

电影元素和新鲜的节目形式吸引广泛的受众的目的,又能提升节目的知识性和思想性,满足受众日益增长的知识文化需求。 《少年派的奇幻漂流》一片已在国内引起了巨大轰动,它震撼的视听效果、唯美的童话语言、巧妙的故事构思和开放式的引人深思的故事结局,共同打造了这部不可多得的优秀电影。利用《少年派》夺人眼球的轰动效应和它引发的各种争议话题,在舞台上重构影片中的经典场景,邀请影片参演人员和电影艺术学家亲临现场,对电影进行多角度的重新解读,迎合当下电影市场发展趋势,以求程度上的吸引受众。 二、企划动机: 利用《少年派的奇幻漂流》里丰富多彩的电影元素、备受争议的主题思想和电影广泛的受众影响力,让节目在《少年派》的轰动效应下,在新颖的节目形式和电影艺术的思想性、艺术性里,达到吸引受众和寓教于乐的目的。 三、栏目基本设定 节目名称:《天堂电影院》;本期主题:少年派的奇幻漂流节目类别:综艺娱乐节目 节目宗旨:通过情景重构的方式,利用即兴情景剧的角色扮演,对电影中涉及的人物、情感、知识和思想进行多角度的解读。 节目目标:通过电影情景的重构,满足观影者想要身临其境的解读电影的愿望,在即兴情景剧的表演中增强节目的悬念性和

广播电视新闻-电视节目策划

1、什么是电视策划?——界定 电视策划——就是对于电视的某一种行为,借助特定电视媒体信息、素材、为实现电视行为的某种目的、目标而提供的创意、思路、方法与对策。 分类:广义和狭义两个方面。 广义的电视节目策划指的是在广阔的范围内,对频道的开办和设置、频道形象包装与推广以及大型的电视综合活动的思维活动过程。 他们是电视台决策人和管理者的智囊团和顾问群,思考的内容是宏观的、全局的、前瞻的。 狭义的电视节目策划指的是对具体栏目或节目的定位、宗旨的构思,以及在这些明确的前提下由创作者从题材的选择、主题的确定、结构的形式、声画内容的融合的最优化的思考与筛选,到最后确定实施拍摄方案的活动过程。 他们是帮助具体栏目和节目的编导的策划群,内容是明确的、具体的、现实的。 2、电视策划:节目-栏目-频道 节目精品化 栏目个性化 频道专业化 3、电视新闻节目的界定 电视新闻是以现代电子技术为传播手段,以声音、画面为传播符号,对新近正在发生、发现的事实的报道。 4、电视新闻节目策划要素 (1)选题策划:

新鲜性:关注社会生活中的新事物,新现象,新问题,传播新信息,新观念。 时效性:媒体实力的体现,抢第一时间。 典型性:发掘新闻内涵,提炼有价值的新闻。 独家性:新闻事件的独家报道/对新闻事件的解释是独家的。卡塔尔半岛电视台 可操性:任何策划得具备可行性(内:人财物/外:政策,社会,自然环境)(2)采访策划; 短新闻采访中:需要记者具有较高的策划和应变能力。 新闻专题节目中:采访是节目的基本构成要素和基本形态。摄像机的介入,让摄像机具有了某种主体意识。要同期录音、现场抓拍、完整调查等等。 从策划角度来说,需要采访记者具备四种意识: 1.换位意识 电视采访是在摄像机镜头前进行,镜头代表假象的公众视点。 换位,指采访记者与被采访对象之间思想、情感的互动与交流,要求采访记者考虑和尊重被采访对象在镜头前的感受,使他们放松紧张情绪,进入自然的谈话状态。 换位也指采访记者与假想的镜头背后的电视观众之间思想情感的互动与交流。采访记者在每一次发问时,要想到这些问题是不是观众想问的。 2、无知意识 其内涵是指,出镜记者在采访过程中要保持一种无知心态和求知的好奇心,有些采访即使知道结果,也要在设计采访问题时从无知开始,到获知结束。 在电视新闻类节目的记者采访中,无知意识束体现为记者采访前的一种谦虚心态,记者保持一颗“大智若愚”的心,才能不为假象干扰。 其次,记者面对采访对象设计问题时,问题的设计要有逻辑性,前一个问题与后一个

女医明妃传原著小说简介_

女医明妃传原著小说简介 导语:《女医·明妃传》是根据历史人物事件改编的古装传奇励志剧。该剧讲述了明代著名女医谭允贤凭借对医学的痴迷和热爱,克服重重困难,开创并建立女医制度,最终成为一代女国医的经历。下面是彩虹作文网小编为您收集整理的资料,希望对您有所帮助。 剧情简介: 大明国体昌盛却礼教严苛,女子地位低下,不得从医,隐疾难治。谭家为医学世家,祖上几代均为御医,因被奸人所陷害而遭遇灭顶之灾,从此留下祖训,后世不得行医。但聪慧的谭允贤从小耳濡目染,偷偷随祖母学习中医知识,不仅悬壶济世、妙手仁心,得到了普通百姓的赞扬和支持,更渐起救天下女子之心。由此,允贤不仅在学医道路上面临重重的困难和阻碍,更要面对封建礼教和世俗观念的冲击。但允贤凭借着对于医学事业的痴迷和热爱,克服重重困难,不仅在医学上广收博采、兼收并蓄、自成一派,更突破严苛的礼教束缚,开创并建立了女医制度,从救人身体到救人灵魂,再由救人到救国,传播弘扬了祖国医学文化,最终成为了一代女国医,名扬天下。 《女医·明妃传》是新丽与唐人共同出品的励志古装大剧,是取材历史人物的生平而改编成的影视作品。该剧由李国立执导,刘诗诗、霍建华、黄轩主演,讲述了中国明代著名女医谈允贤的传奇一生。谈允贤(刘诗诗饰)凭借对医学事业的痴迷和热爱,克服重重困难,开创并建立女医制度,最终成为一代女国医。 《女医·明妃传》是根据历史上著名的女名医谈允贤为原型改编成型。由刘诗诗主演谈允贤,霍建华扮演明英宗朱祁镇,两个人的爱情故事就在明朝历史中前行,喜欢明英宗的谈允贤跟随他在“土木堡”之变中会有什么样的经历。回到大明的朱祁镇发现皇位已经让自己弟弟登上。面对这样的情况朱祁镇会有什么样的动作,谈允贤跟随他在大明飘摇的历史中会什么样的结局 《女医明妃传》小说结局是什么? 结局:朱祁镇历尽艰难终于重归故土,允贤面临情感的两难选择,却发现朱祁钰早已被权力蒙蔽了心智。经历了人生坎坷波折的允贤从未放弃事业的追求。她在宫廷中开创了女医制度,又在民间设立医馆,广招学徒,既做到了悬壶济世,又从实际意义上提高了古代女性的地位。多年后,明朝政局稳定,朱祁镇主动离开权力中心,遍走江湖,只为寻找允贤共度此生。 谈允贤 (1461年-1556年) ,中国古代4位(晋代鲍姑、西汉义妁、宋代张小娘子、明代谈允贤)女名医之一。 其祖父谈复、祖母茹氏为当时名医,伯父谈经官至户部主事,父亲谈纲官至南京刑部主事,母钱氏,有一弟谈一凤。谈允贤自小聪慧,祖母就让她学医,就在祖母的教导下学会的精湛的医术,祖母去世前将一生所收集、编写的药方病理都传给了谈允贤。谈允贤后嫁杨姓男子为妻,婚后不久患上气血失调,就自我诊治、试药,后来生了三女和一子杨濂,每当子女有病,她都亲自为他们诊治。直至其祖母去世,她才真正在外行医。 在当时的封建社会中,许多上流社会的妇女因男女之防,不愿请男医生诊治,因此常常发生贻误病情的情况,谈允贤女医的名声使这些妇女纷纷找她治病,在许多成功的案例后,谈允贤的名声也渐渐的传遍各地。 50岁时谈允贤将祖母留下的药方病理汇集自己多年行医的经验,写成了一

电视节目策划方案范本doc

电视节目策划方案范本 篇一:电视节目策划书范文 《电视节目策划书范文XX年6月7日》《电视节目策划书范文》简介: 这是一档倡导“聪明+勤奋+勇气=成功”的职业理念,鼓励人们用科学的职场视角剖 《电视节目策划书范文》正文开始>> 这是一档倡导“聪明+勤奋+勇气=成功”的职业理念,鼓励人们用科学的职场视角剖析自己,用积极的态度改变自己职业生涯的职业励志节目。 这是一次最有生命力的“真人秀”节目尝试,无论从内容到形式依然突出“绝对挑战”核心理念的节目,其“绝对”之处体现在精心设计的商场上智商和情商的较量把电视节目的游戏成分淡化了下来,应该算是迄今为止最贴近生活最有生活原型素材的“纪实秀”。与虚构游戏类真人秀不同,现实的商业特性锻造了更高级别真人秀的节目特性。 这是挑战专业类节目收视率瓶颈的一次积极尝试。统计得知,良好的系列节目中的故事特性和悬念特性能有效的积累收视,将稳定的专业节目收视人群改变为“专业加戏剧”的 收视人群对《绝对挑战》未来的收视环境有非常好的突破作用。

这是一次对节目整合营销的一次有益尝试 一、节目的立足点——《绝对挑战》不得不做的改变 1、传承“真实”,保证收视源动力 《绝对挑战》的职业梦想很高,但“绝对真实”。它涵盖的内容最实际:职业机会、地位、金钱、社会认可、精神欲望,所以,当我们强化这个梦想并为这个梦想提供更具含金量机会的时候,没有人会不注目。我们将严格保持原有节目的“绝对真实”:真实的企业参与,真实的高职位、真实的应聘者、真实的招聘结果,谁会实现这个梦想呢,要实现这样的梦想需要具备什么条件呢?如何通过实际的努力实现这个梦想?这些真实的心理对位构成了最强劲的收视源动力,这是和别的游戏类真人秀最大的不同。 2、强化戏剧表现打破专业类节目的收视平庸现状 《绝对挑战》进入今年,收视大幅攀升,几乎是去年收视分额的两倍,大家的努力为节目赢得了可喜的收视基础。但同时,节目制作水平的日益精良并没有最大限度的弥补节目专业性带来的收视不利,导致收视横向比较平庸。在调查中,我们发现观众更期待在周末看到一个“真实的戏剧”。《绝对挑战》系列节目更象一部“城市幸存者”,每一个测试项目中都包括了团队合作,个人贡献,领导才能,压力对抗等等 办公室必备的基本因素和戏剧冲突,而复杂的多的人物

热门-新闻采访策划书范文4篇

新闻采访策划书范文4篇 一、采访目的: 响应我校大学生领导力培养项目,通过采访各学院心理部部长或学生会主席,借鉴和吸收其管理、组织经验,为自身领导力的提升和发展提供引导,并吸纳整合至协会的发展建设中,为协会的发展建设提供全新的视角和广阔的途径,并提升协会内部凝聚力和向心力,提升成员认同感和归属感。 二、采访意义: 契合心理协会“阳光心态,成功人生”的活动主题,本次采访活动将使学生在采访的筹备、实施和反思过程中实现组织、表达、交际能理得综合提升。通过小组合作方式,提升团队协作能力,在实践中提升个人能力,并藉此提升协会的凝聚力和向心力。扩大协会的影响范围,促进协会的进一步发展,树立协会的形象。 三、采访对象: 管理学院、光电信息与计算机学院、能源与动力工程学院、出版印刷与艺术设计学院、理学院、机械工程学院、医疗器械与食品学院、外语学院、环境与建筑学院学生会心理部部长或主席。 四、采访方案 前期:

1、采访团分组:(负责人:各部门部长) 各部门参加活动者均分为2组,每组3人之内(需要录 制DV的小组由 组织部分配一名宣传部同学携DV随行)各小组选定负 责人, 并上报组织部。 2、联系相关受访人以及商定相关采访时间: 各部门部长负责 3、小礼品的准备: 由受访团小组讨论决定,金额限制在20元之内 中期: 采访思路设置:(注:红色字体部分为必问问题) 第一篇章:领导物语(倾听心语,感悟成功) 要求:围绕受访人对“领导力”这个概念的认识情况 问题示例: 1、怎样认识“领导力”这一概念/领导力素质包括哪些? 2、培养积极心态的必要性? 3、结合自身经历,阐述怎样在实践中提升自身的领导力?

女医明妃传经典台词大全

女医明妃传经典台词大全 经典台词: 人这一辈子那么长,不能总把心思花在难过上。 已入初秋,万花还未败落,泛着初秋的一点雅黄,却还残存盛夏的墨绿,仿佛万花不甘心被秋叶抢了风头,还要挣扎着向人间绽放晚颜。 别说爱谁别说可是 回忆就浅尝辄止 得失离散总会又周而复始 执白雁为礼以求好合 走,只为留的那天。 不相见不相见那一人那一面/ 也不怨你我错过的流年/ 某一年某一眼谁留恋谁无言/ 擦过肩缘分就别再争辩/ 若不是那一眼辗转的相思/ 爱一人用一生不自知/ 到如今满城风雨也别解释/ 用尽天下的药石/

难解人间的相思/ 大雨将至满地潮湿/ 从前的电光火石/ 多年以后每段故事/ 原来结尾都相似/ 别说爱谁别说可是/ 回忆就浅尝辄止/ 得失离散总会又周而复始/ “我敬你,怕你,却唯独不爱你”朕是天子朕会得到你 宫中女子千人有疾而不得医 只得自判其症胡乱取药 庙宇道观尚且能设粥棚 以施贫苦之人 我即为贵妃为何不可为皇上 广施恩德医之疗之 所谓医女不过一个名号 未占朝廷官署未支后宫财米 为何诸位大人咄咄逼人 硬要视我为妖妃恶妇 欲除之而后快 都是你这个昏君

因为一个女人 把我送进天牢 我要杀光你们 我要用整个大明 为我的这条断腿陪葬 我是皇帝也是郑齐 什么菊花沉香蒸肉圆 明明就是神截开解散 到底是谁推荐的人 简直是有辰医德 什么时候,我在他面前,到了需要演戏的地步 以后朕不会在让任何欺负你了 你还是可以把我当作原来郑齐一样 他千辛万苦把我从狼堆里救出来,差点饿死冻死,好不容易等来了救兵,可你却听信谗言,要杀了我的救命恩人,我要不以死相报的话,还有脸活在这世上吗 没有,我一直都把你当好朋友。 我连大明皇帝都不怕,难道会怕你瓦剌太师 贽白雁为礼,以求好合。 你当女太医,我就给你当一辈子药童。 他要杀就让他杀吧,反正古往今来敢车裂皇帝的,只有他一个,大不了我就陪皇上在黄泉底下等着大明踏平瓦

相关文档
相关文档 最新文档